WEBVTT 00:01.920 --> 00:04.980 Prof: Anyhow, so today I'm going to try and 00:04.982 --> 00:06.672 wrap up a few loose ends. 00:06.670 --> 00:12.360 So I'm going to try and talk about the high water mark of 00:12.362 --> 00:17.752 finance which is basically CAPM and Black-Scholes, 00:17.750 --> 00:20.990 both of which we've almost talked about, 00:20.990 --> 00:25.030 almost finished talking about, and I'm going to talk in the 00:25.029 --> 00:28.929 middle about Social Security which we never finished, 00:28.930 --> 00:31.480 my Social Security plan. 00:31.480 --> 00:34.430 So I hope to deal with all three of these things today. 00:34.430 --> 00:39.710 So just to wrap up the CAPM, the CAPM had two main ideas. 00:39.710 --> 00:45.460 The first idea was diversification and the second 00:45.457 --> 00:51.557 main idea, as we said, was the tradeoff between risk 00:51.563 --> 00:53.363 and return. 00:53.360 --> 00:55.440 Shakespeare had both of these ideas. 00:55.440 --> 00:58.450 He understood that you're safer if you've got each of your boats 00:58.452 --> 01:01.152 on a different ocean, and he understood that if 01:01.152 --> 01:05.002 you're going to take a high risk you'd better get a high return 01:05.001 --> 01:07.611 otherwise nobody is willing to take it. 01:07.609 --> 01:09.489 And so he made that very clear. 01:09.489 --> 01:12.569 In fact I think the whole point of the play is about economics, 01:12.569 --> 01:14.969 The Merchant of Venice, and he made both of these 01:14.968 --> 01:17.588 principles very clear, but he couldn't quantify them 01:17.587 --> 01:19.237 and he couldn't mathematize them, 01:19.239 --> 01:22.289 and the Capital Asset Pricing Model gives a mathematical, 01:22.290 --> 01:26.490 quantifiable form to both and a quite shocking recommendation in 01:26.492 --> 01:27.362 both cases. 01:27.360 --> 01:29.660 So just to draw those two pictures, 01:29.659 --> 01:31.579 for those of you who didn't hear it last night, 01:31.580 --> 01:38.240 if you do Tobin's famous picture, this is the 01:38.242 --> 01:46.272 Markowitz-Tobin Capital Market Line they called it. 01:46.269 --> 01:49.219 It's very important to keep straight what's on the diagram. 01:49.220 --> 01:54.010 There's the standard deviation of any asset per dollar. 01:54.010 --> 01:55.840 So here I'm writing the price. 01:55.840 --> 02:00.370 So it's per dollar, and here is the expectation of 02:00.371 --> 02:02.501 the asset per dollar. 02:02.500 --> 02:05.200 So pi of Y, I'm calling that the price. 02:05.200 --> 02:10.440 So this is per dollar. 02:10.438 --> 02:13.128 And I'm not going to go over what we derived before, 02:13.128 --> 02:16.778 but we noticed that if you took all the risky assets, 02:16.780 --> 02:19.530 any risky asset's going to have per dollar, 02:19.530 --> 02:22.370 if it's priced, some standard deviation and 02:22.366 --> 02:23.646 some expectation. 02:23.650 --> 02:26.180 You can write down all the risky assets, 02:26.175 --> 02:29.605 and you can combine them, and you'll get a possibility 02:29.610 --> 02:31.490 set that looks like this. 02:31.490 --> 02:35.660 So the diversification already shows up in this picture because 02:35.662 --> 02:39.632 if you combine this asset and this asset you're going to get 02:39.633 --> 02:43.473 possibilities by putting half of your money in each, 02:43.470 --> 02:45.200 not on the straight line between them, 02:45.199 --> 02:48.119 but on some curved line that's much better because you're 02:48.122 --> 02:49.222 reducing your risk. 02:49.220 --> 02:55.740 So Markowitz already had that curve and this picture in mind. 02:55.740 --> 03:00.190 Tobin added the riskless asset, which he put here, 03:00.188 --> 03:02.488 and then he said, well, if there's a riskless 03:02.485 --> 03:05.505 asset everybody's going to do the same thing and everyone's 03:05.513 --> 03:07.343 going to choose the same point. 03:07.340 --> 03:13.460 It's better for everybody, so this is the optimal risky 03:13.461 --> 03:19.131 portfolio and it has to be equal to the market, 03:19.128 --> 03:21.788 because if everybody's smart enough to figure out what to do 03:21.793 --> 03:23.693 they're all going to do the same thing, 03:23.688 --> 03:27.848 and whatever everybody holds that's by definition the market. 03:27.848 --> 03:34.598 So Tobin showed that everybody should choose something on this 03:34.601 --> 03:41.021 capital market line and so everybody should split his money 03:41.020 --> 03:45.890 between the market and a riskless asset. 03:45.889 --> 03:48.789 Put your money in the bank or own the entire market. 03:48.788 --> 03:52.788 That was his recommendation and that was the beginning of the 03:52.794 --> 03:54.934 whole idea of index investing. 03:54.930 --> 03:58.530 So that was the first idea, first, most important idea. 03:58.530 --> 04:03.220 Now, how could you test this? 04:03.218 --> 04:07.578 Well, you could simply test every fund in history and 04:07.580 --> 04:12.610 compare so called experts and see if those guys could get you 04:12.611 --> 04:14.291 above this line. 04:14.288 --> 04:17.888 So by the way, the slope of the line, 04:17.889 --> 04:21.989 one more thing, is the slope equals Sharpe 04:21.990 --> 04:22.990 ratio. 04:22.990 --> 04:25.860 So everybody's trying to get the highest Sharpe ratio they 04:25.857 --> 04:28.227 can, and if you have this portfolio 04:28.226 --> 04:31.316 you've made a mistake, you haven't held the optimal 04:31.319 --> 04:34.179 one, then the slope of your performance will be a lower 04:34.175 --> 04:35.545 Sharpe ratio than that. 04:35.550 --> 04:37.830 The slope of this, which is the Sharpe ratio of 04:37.829 --> 04:39.959 that point, is worse than the slope of that, 04:39.959 --> 04:42.139 which is the Sharpe ratio of this point. 04:42.139 --> 04:46.149 And the Sharpe ratio, remember, is (the expectation 04:46.151 --> 04:50.811 per dollar minus what you can get in the riskless asset per 04:50.805 --> 04:55.775 dollar) divided by the started deviation of Y per dollar, 04:55.779 --> 04:57.529 let's say. 04:57.529 --> 05:00.069 So that's just the slope of this line. 05:00.069 --> 05:03.499 So we can measure performance of a portfolio manger by the 05:03.504 --> 05:04.414 Sharpe ratio. 05:04.410 --> 05:06.640 Everyone should try and get the highest Sharpe ratio. 05:06.639 --> 05:10.209 The upshot of diversification is you should buy a little bit 05:10.206 --> 05:13.406 of every stock in the economy no matter how small, 05:13.410 --> 05:15.120 no matter how big, no matter how safe, 05:15.120 --> 05:17.610 no matter how risky, you should spread your money 05:17.610 --> 05:18.650 across everything. 05:18.649 --> 05:20.979 That's the recommendation of Tobin. 05:20.980 --> 05:22.950 And it relies, of course, on everybody else 05:22.952 --> 05:25.022 being rational, so everybody else is choosing 05:25.019 --> 05:25.959 the right thing. 05:25.959 --> 05:30.959 Then you can just piggyback and do what everybody else is doing. 05:30.959 --> 05:32.429 So that's the first thing. 05:32.430 --> 05:35.060 Very shocking, as I said, at first glance 05:35.060 --> 05:39.010 you'd think someone who loves risk would just invest in risky 05:39.007 --> 05:43.087 stocks and people who are very risk averse would just invest in 05:43.086 --> 05:44.266 safe stocks. 05:44.269 --> 05:45.729 Tobin says, no, no, no, no. 05:45.730 --> 05:49.110 If you're risk averse you should just put most of your 05:49.107 --> 05:52.737 money in the bank and hold a little bit of every stock. 05:52.740 --> 05:53.850 So you're here somewhere. 05:53.850 --> 05:56.820 If you're very risk tolerant you shouldn't just concentrate 05:56.822 --> 05:57.952 on the risky stocks. 05:57.949 --> 06:00.379 You should buy the same proportion of all stocks as 06:00.379 --> 06:02.569 everyone else, but you should borrow the money 06:02.567 --> 06:04.267 to do it and maybe way up here. 06:04.269 --> 06:10.509 And people who borrow money to invest that's called leveraging. 06:10.509 --> 06:14.299 So that's idea number one, the crucial idea. 06:14.300 --> 06:15.960 There are a lot of ideas mixed in that, 06:15.959 --> 06:18.589 and as I said, you can test it by seeing if 06:18.589 --> 06:22.049 anyone can beat the market-- is there anyone historically 06:22.052 --> 06:24.992 that has had a higher Sharpe ratio than the market. 06:24.990 --> 06:32.470 In 1967 when all of this was being tested there was a famous 06:32.473 --> 06:40.723 book called A Random Walk Down Wall Street written by Malkiel, 06:40.720 --> 06:45.760 which I recommend you read. 06:45.759 --> 06:48.069 He gives the history of tests of whether people could beat the 06:48.069 --> 06:48.409 market. 06:48.410 --> 06:51.180 Of course many people beat the market for short periods of 06:51.178 --> 06:51.518 time. 06:51.519 --> 06:52.839 Then they totally collapse. 06:52.839 --> 06:56.689 And then some people beat the market for 20 years in a row and 06:56.692 --> 06:59.082 then retire, but there are so few of those 06:59.084 --> 07:02.024 people that it looks like just by random dumb luck you could 07:02.024 --> 07:03.374 get almost those people. 07:03.370 --> 07:05.610 On the other hand there are some people like Warren Buffet 07:05.605 --> 07:07.525 who seem to beat the market for 40 or 50 years. 07:07.528 --> 07:10.668 It's really hard to believe that that's all just luck. 07:10.670 --> 07:15.250 And so that's one test of the thing. 07:15.250 --> 07:19.340 The second idea of the Capital Asset Pricing Model is risk and 07:19.336 --> 07:19.936 return. 07:19.939 --> 07:24.549 And so now if we assume--so all this graph, 07:24.550 --> 07:29.870 by the way, assumed quadratic utilities, 07:29.870 --> 07:32.630 quadratic or mean variance utilities, 07:32.629 --> 07:39.539 quadratic utility and common probabilities. 07:39.540 --> 07:41.660 So everybody knew what the probabilities were of the 07:41.658 --> 07:43.748 different states, so you know how to measure the 07:43.754 --> 07:46.334 covariance and the variance and all that because you know what 07:46.329 --> 07:48.059 the probabilities are to measure over. 07:48.060 --> 07:52.480 So here, having assumed that, it turns out that you just 07:52.478 --> 07:57.538 apply the principle that we saw the first few days of class, 07:57.540 --> 08:06.150 that the price is going to equal the marginal utility, 08:06.149 --> 08:07.549 not the total utility. 08:07.550 --> 08:10.850 Price is going to equal marginal utility and if the 08:10.850 --> 08:14.550 price equals the marginal utility the marginal utility is 08:14.547 --> 08:18.087 going to be-- depends, according to this 08:18.086 --> 08:22.636 assumption of quadratic utilities as we showed, 08:22.639 --> 08:27.069 depends on expectation. 08:27.069 --> 08:30.769 So this is the price of Y, so let's just call it pi of Y 08:30.773 --> 08:32.123 like I did before. 08:32.120 --> 08:38.970 It depends on the expectation of Y and it depends on the 08:38.972 --> 08:43.212 covariance of Y with the market. 08:43.210 --> 08:47.270 We've assumed with quadratic utilities that people only care 08:47.269 --> 08:51.109 about the mean and the variance, so you'd have expected the 08:51.105 --> 08:54.445 marginal utility of any single asset to depend on its mean and 08:54.447 --> 08:57.107 its variance, but it's the marginal utility. 08:57.110 --> 08:59.450 It's what it adds to what you've already got. 08:59.450 --> 09:02.430 So it adds expectation because expectation's additive, 09:02.428 --> 09:05.398 but when you add another stock to what you already have, 09:05.399 --> 09:08.649 the variance of the whole portfolio changes according to 09:08.647 --> 09:12.247 the covariance of the new thing with what you already had, 09:12.250 --> 09:13.950 and everybody already had the market. 09:13.950 --> 09:18.210 So given that you know that the price, 09:18.210 --> 09:22.210 mathematically therefore, the price has to equal 09:22.208 --> 09:27.318 something times the expectation of Y plus something times the 09:27.316 --> 09:30.376 covariance of Y with the market. 09:30.379 --> 09:32.349 But that's true for all Y. 09:32.350 --> 09:35.830 In particular it's true for the riskless asset. 09:35.830 --> 09:40.660 So the riskless asset pays 1 for sure, has no covariance with 09:40.664 --> 09:45.344 anything like the market, and its price is 1 over (1 r). 09:45.340 --> 09:48.440 So therefore A has to be 1 over (1 r). 09:48.440 --> 09:51.710 So we know that this has to be (1 r). 09:51.710 --> 09:55.030 And then B could be whatever it is. 09:55.029 --> 09:57.309 The covariance, by the way, is going to be bad, 09:57.307 --> 09:58.247 so this is minus. 09:58.250 --> 10:00.590 And then B, you have to figure B out. 10:00.590 --> 10:04.100 So you don't know what B is a priori. 10:04.100 --> 10:05.780 You don't know what the interest rate is either. 10:05.778 --> 10:07.768 You had to see that in the market. 10:07.769 --> 10:10.549 Once you know the price of one asset, 10:10.548 --> 10:12.518 and you know its correlation with the market, 10:12.519 --> 10:15.909 if you knew this price, and you know the expectation of 10:15.905 --> 10:17.385 Y, and you know the covariance 10:17.386 --> 10:19.026 with the market that will tell you B. 10:19.028 --> 10:22.738 So once you've given one price of a risky asset, 10:22.740 --> 10:25.080 like of the market as a whole, you're going to be able to 10:25.078 --> 10:27.498 figure out the price of every other asset because from that 10:27.503 --> 10:30.253 one price you can deduce B, and once you have B you can 10:30.250 --> 10:31.190 price everything. 10:31.190 --> 10:34.100 So that's the second idea, risk and return. 10:34.100 --> 10:37.180 And you can see it graphically and more dramatically, 10:37.178 --> 10:39.888 because if I take that same equation, 10:39.889 --> 10:42.629 this is called the covariance pricing formula, 10:42.629 --> 10:47.379 you take that and divide by pi of Y you get 1 equals 10:47.381 --> 10:51.671 expectation of Y divided by the price of Y-- 10:51.668 --> 10:59.038 dividing both sides by pi of Y-- minus B times the covariance 10:59.038 --> 11:03.458 of (Y over the price of Y) with M. 11:03.460 --> 11:07.490 So that just tells me the expectation and the covariance 11:07.493 --> 11:11.093 of a dollar's worth, just like this was a dollar's 11:11.086 --> 11:11.816 worth. 11:11.820 --> 11:15.020 This was per dollar and this is per dollar, 11:15.019 --> 11:20.419 so if you put the covariance of Y and the pi of Y down here, 11:20.418 --> 11:25.028 and M over here, and here you put expectation Y 11:25.033 --> 11:28.983 over pi of Y, this just says this is just a 11:28.980 --> 11:31.020 constant, and this is a constant, 11:31.023 --> 11:33.383 so it says this and this are linearly related. 11:33.379 --> 11:36.059 These are all securities who have price 1. 11:36.058 --> 11:38.528 There has to be a linear relationship between their 11:38.530 --> 11:41.600 expectation per dollar and their covariance per dollar with the 11:41.596 --> 11:42.136 market. 11:42.139 --> 11:44.949 And as the covariance gets higher the return gets higher. 11:44.950 --> 11:49.500 So if you take a stock with a high covariance it's going to 11:49.504 --> 11:52.494 have to have a high expected return. 11:52.490 --> 11:53.990 That's exactly what Shakespeare said. 11:53.990 --> 11:57.710 If it's more risky people won't hold it unless it's got a higher 11:57.711 --> 12:00.961 return, which means you can buy it for a cheap price. 12:00.960 --> 12:03.520 So its price is less than its expectation. 12:03.519 --> 12:07.039 But the difference with Shakespeare is we've quantified 12:07.043 --> 12:07.503 risk. 12:07.500 --> 12:10.030 It's not what you would have thought, variance, 12:10.028 --> 12:11.018 it's covariance. 12:11.019 --> 12:11.719 And that's it. 12:11.720 --> 12:14.820 Those are the two big ideas and you could test-- 12:14.820 --> 12:22.510 so this is called the Security Market Line, 12:22.509 --> 12:25.689 and you could test this by asking is every stock-- 12:25.690 --> 12:27.530 so if you look at every stock last year, 12:27.528 --> 12:30.338 you look at its covariance, you put a point here, 12:30.340 --> 12:32.750 then you look this year at its expected return, 12:32.750 --> 12:34.630 of course some stocks are going to be wild, 12:34.629 --> 12:37.299 but you average over a bunch of stock and a bunch of years. 12:37.298 --> 12:41.228 Do you get things that lie in a straight line or close to a 12:41.226 --> 12:42.306 straight line? 12:42.308 --> 12:46.488 And Sharpe, in 1967, found that amazingly when you 12:46.485 --> 12:51.935 did that you got--so I described last night exactly what his test 12:51.937 --> 12:52.617 was. 12:52.620 --> 12:55.620 You got something that looked incredibly close to a straight 12:55.624 --> 12:56.494 line like that. 12:56.490 --> 12:59.370 So this was the greatest triumph in the history of the 12:59.368 --> 13:01.138 social sciences, it was called, 13:01.144 --> 13:03.224 because you had huge amounts of data, 13:03.220 --> 13:07.830 huge capacity to test things, a shocking conclusion, 13:07.830 --> 13:10.780 a shockingly precise theory to test, 13:10.778 --> 13:13.978 and it fit the line so incredibly closely. 13:13.980 --> 13:17.110 And it just swept, it made a huge impression in 13:17.105 --> 13:21.115 finance and in economics and lots of Nobel Prizes were given 13:21.115 --> 13:21.995 for this. 13:22.000 --> 13:23.030 Sharpe won a Nobel Prize. 13:23.029 --> 13:24.359 Markowitz won a Nobel Prize. 13:24.360 --> 13:26.520 Tobin won a Nobel Prize. 13:26.519 --> 13:28.559 Lintner died. 13:28.558 --> 13:33.308 He would have won a Nobel Prize too. 13:33.308 --> 13:36.778 So this was the first major triumph, the most important 13:36.783 --> 13:39.623 triumph of finance, the Capital Asset Pricing 13:39.615 --> 13:40.255 Model. 13:40.259 --> 13:43.729 Now, as it happens, as the theory's been tested 13:43.730 --> 13:48.260 over and over again every year since 1967 it's performed more 13:48.259 --> 13:49.769 and more poorly. 13:49.769 --> 13:54.129 And so now when you do this you get points that look like this, 13:54.129 --> 13:55.999 and like that, and like this, 13:56.003 --> 13:59.753 and they don't seem to lie on a straight line at all, 13:59.750 --> 14:03.410 and it's pretty shocking how up until '67 or the early '70s that 14:03.408 --> 14:06.838 it seemed to work out perfectly and now it doesn't work very 14:06.836 --> 14:07.356 well. 14:07.360 --> 14:11.100 And this business they've also discovered, according to this 14:11.102 --> 14:13.072 you couldn't beat the market. 14:13.070 --> 14:15.780 So how do you test whether something beats the market? 14:15.778 --> 14:17.248 You can pick a bunch of people and say, 14:17.250 --> 14:19.460 "Could they beat the market," 14:19.455 --> 14:22.935 or you can actually just make up a strategy yourself like buy 14:22.937 --> 14:24.097 only new stocks. 14:24.100 --> 14:27.070 Just every year buy the stocks that have come onto the S&P 14:27.065 --> 14:30.125 500 for the first time, or just buy the stocks that are 14:30.133 --> 14:31.533 the biggest 10 percent. 14:31.528 --> 14:34.398 And it turns out some of those strategies actually do beat the 14:34.397 --> 14:34.817 market. 14:34.820 --> 14:38.070 So I don't have time to go into the details, you know, 14:38.068 --> 14:40.458 that is they lie above or below here. 14:40.460 --> 14:43.680 So the theory has come into--so theory and doubt. 14:43.678 --> 14:47.628 And so what I'm going to talk about next week is, 14:47.625 --> 14:51.815 and it certainly doesn't explain the current crisis, 14:51.817 --> 14:55.267 so I want next week to explain crisis. 14:55.269 --> 15:00.099 So next week I'm going to end by giving another theory which 15:00.099 --> 15:05.419 is going to explain the crisis and be different from this one, 15:05.418 --> 15:08.558 but of course it hasn't been tested over 30 years or 50 years 15:08.561 --> 15:09.191 like CAPM. 15:09.190 --> 15:11.420 CAPM looked great for the first 20 years, 15:11.418 --> 15:14.748 so whatever I say next week will probably turn out to be 90 15:14.753 --> 15:17.203 percent wrong, but at the moment it looks 15:17.202 --> 15:17.942 pretty good. 15:17.940 --> 15:20.530 And I didn't want to spend half the course on it in case in 20 15:20.525 --> 15:22.005 years it seemed to be ridiculous. 15:22.009 --> 15:24.879 But anyway, I'm going to present it anyway to those of 15:24.876 --> 15:26.876 you who want to hear it next week, 15:26.879 --> 15:29.429 and it'll be, I think, understandable and 15:29.427 --> 15:32.737 down to earth and it'll invoke a very basic thing. 15:32.740 --> 15:34.980 Nowhere in this model did we take into account, 15:34.984 --> 15:37.674 you know, when we say people leverage that means they're 15:37.667 --> 15:39.957 borrowing money and choosing to go up here. 15:39.960 --> 15:43.570 We haven't taken into account that they have to pay the money 15:43.570 --> 15:47.180 back, and who's going to trust them to pay the money back? 15:47.178 --> 15:49.508 And forcing them to do something to guarantee they're 15:49.509 --> 15:52.239 going to pay the money back is going to change the theory in a 15:52.243 --> 15:54.883 critical way, which I'll get to next week. 15:54.879 --> 15:56.819 Now, one last thing about the theory, 15:56.820 --> 16:00.790 as I say, you test it by seeing--nobody should be above 16:00.792 --> 16:04.472 this line and nobody should be above this line, 16:04.470 --> 16:06.910 but of course you can find people above this line. 16:06.908 --> 16:10.738 Swensen, to take a famous Yale example, is above this line. 16:10.740 --> 16:16.520 And you can find people above this line, Ellington. 16:16.519 --> 16:18.839 So Ellington, let's say, above this line. 16:18.840 --> 16:20.440 All right, so hedge funds. 16:20.440 --> 16:27.090 Let's call it an anonymous hedge fund since we're on camera 16:27.090 --> 16:30.760 now, hedge fund, hedge fund E. 16:30.759 --> 16:33.039 So the question is, is that luck, 16:33.039 --> 16:37.529 they just did it a few years in both cases like 15 years apiece, 16:37.530 --> 16:39.670 or does it mean something? 16:39.668 --> 16:42.408 All right, well, so you can measure the, 16:42.408 --> 16:44.968 you know, if you believe this theory and you just say, 16:44.970 --> 16:47.590 okay, let's say the theory's 99 percent true, 16:47.590 --> 16:50.070 it's just that there are a few people who really do beat the 16:50.068 --> 16:52.278 market, then you can decide by looking 16:52.279 --> 16:56.159 at these graphs just how good is Swensen relative to the market? 16:56.158 --> 16:59.318 How good is this hedge fund relative to the market? 16:59.320 --> 17:02.480 And so you have a way of calibrating and measuring how 17:02.476 --> 17:03.486 well people do. 17:03.490 --> 17:06.520 So I don't have time to get into that, but I would measure 17:06.516 --> 17:09.646 the quality of a hedge fund by its marginal Sharpe ratio. 17:09.650 --> 17:12.010 How much does having access to this hedge fund, 17:12.006 --> 17:14.406 if you added it to your portfolio, increase your 17:14.413 --> 17:17.133 portfolio hedge ratio [correction: Sharpe ratio]? 17:17.130 --> 17:19.430 That's, I think, the right measure of how good a 17:19.426 --> 17:20.206 hedge fund is. 17:20.210 --> 17:23.460 And the right measure of how good Swensen is, 17:23.455 --> 17:25.665 is, what's his Sharpe ratio? 17:25.670 --> 17:27.530 And so there's a different criterion. 17:27.529 --> 17:28.769 I keep emphasizing this. 17:28.769 --> 17:32.639 Swensen is managing an entire portfolio so you have to measure 17:32.644 --> 17:35.994 him on how's he done for Yale, because Yale's not going to 17:35.986 --> 17:37.506 combine him with something else. 17:37.509 --> 17:39.429 It's just holding what he holds. 17:39.430 --> 17:41.290 So it's his Sharpe ratio. 17:41.288 --> 17:42.958 But Ellington, you're going to combine 17:42.961 --> 17:44.501 Ellington with some other stuff. 17:44.500 --> 17:47.020 So Swensen might invest in Ellington, but ten million other 17:47.019 --> 17:47.409 things. 17:47.410 --> 17:51.050 And so you have to say how much is Ellington going to help 17:51.051 --> 17:52.651 Swensen's Sharpe ratio? 17:52.650 --> 17:55.430 So instead of Swensen's Sharpe ratio how much is Ellington 17:55.434 --> 17:57.394 going to help the market Sharpe ratio? 17:57.390 --> 18:01.810 So that's how you should measure a hedge fund, 18:01.805 --> 18:06.805 its marginal Sharpe ratio, and Swensen by his Sharpe 18:06.807 --> 18:07.787 ratio. 18:07.788 --> 18:20.388 So I'd say measure Swensen performance by Sharpe ratio, 18:20.390 --> 18:30.530 measure hedge fund performance by marginal Sharpe ratio, 18:30.528 --> 18:35.268 because you'd be crazy to put all your money in a hedge fund. 18:35.269 --> 18:37.909 The only people who do it are the partners of the hedge fund 18:37.905 --> 18:40.495 who are sort of forced to do it because that's how they can 18:40.498 --> 18:43.308 persuade investors that they're really paying attention to their 18:43.313 --> 18:46.763 fund, because all their money's at 18:46.757 --> 18:47.377 risk. 18:47.380 --> 18:48.110 So that's it. 18:48.109 --> 18:49.369 That's the basic bottom line. 18:49.368 --> 18:54.838 So are there any questions before I now move on from this? 18:54.838 --> 18:57.718 We talked about this last night and we talked about it for the 18:57.723 --> 18:58.673 last two lectures. 18:58.670 --> 19:01.040 All right, so it's a high water mark as I say; 19:01.038 --> 19:05.308 incredibly precise prediction and incredibly close to the 19:05.314 --> 19:08.754 facts, at least in 1967 but not after that. 19:08.750 --> 19:12.980 Now, I want to move to an aside of Social Security before I come 19:12.980 --> 19:17.080 back to Black-Scholes which is the last high water mark of the 19:17.076 --> 19:18.416 standard theory. 19:18.420 --> 19:23.690 Remember the upshot of what we've talked about so far. 19:23.690 --> 19:38.210 The upshot of this is that the market will get a higher return. 19:38.210 --> 19:39.700 Oh, by the way, I'd say one other thing. 19:39.700 --> 19:45.360 What is the standard critique of this theory? 19:45.358 --> 19:47.598 So of course everybody else has seen that the theory doesn't 19:47.603 --> 19:47.873 work. 19:47.868 --> 19:50.318 So what is their explanation for why? 19:50.318 --> 19:53.218 What's the old explanation for why the theory isn't working so 19:53.217 --> 19:53.737 well now? 19:53.740 --> 19:57.380 The explanation is that in the old days what was thought of as 19:57.375 --> 19:59.875 the market was just all American stocks. 19:59.880 --> 20:02.190 But now it's pretty obvious, in fact it should have been 20:02.191 --> 20:03.411 obvious from the beginning. 20:03.410 --> 20:07.450 And so Swensen realized it early on that Markowitz's advice 20:07.446 --> 20:09.776 is to diversify, diversify, diversify, 20:09.782 --> 20:11.522 not just into all American stocks, 20:11.519 --> 20:14.219 into everything all over the world and all kinds of assets 20:14.221 --> 20:15.551 that aren't stocks at all. 20:15.548 --> 20:18.588 So what you measure as the market shouldn't just be 20:18.594 --> 20:19.694 American stocks. 20:19.690 --> 20:22.720 It should be the world portfolio, but how do you 20:22.717 --> 20:24.647 measure the world portfolio? 20:24.650 --> 20:27.210 That's hard to do, and so people have tried to 20:27.207 --> 20:30.497 maintain that the reason the theory doesn't work is because 20:30.503 --> 20:33.293 we've got the wrong M in all these equations. 20:33.288 --> 20:37.008 So that would be a nice way of fixing the theory. 20:37.009 --> 20:39.699 I doubt if that's going to help in the end. 20:39.700 --> 20:43.550 So my problem about collateral is a different look at it. 20:43.548 --> 20:47.888 But anyhow, so the market according to the theory will get 20:47.887 --> 20:52.147 a higher return than bonds, and of course that's true. 20:52.150 --> 20:56.900 The market has a very high positive covariance with itself 20:56.900 --> 20:59.400 so a very low price up here. 20:59.400 --> 21:02.100 It's high covariance with itself, so a low price. 21:02.098 --> 21:04.368 Compared to its expectation the price is low, 21:04.369 --> 21:06.949 so you're paying much less than the expectation. 21:06.950 --> 21:10.000 So then when you see what actually happens it's going to 21:10.000 --> 21:11.610 look much higher than that. 21:11.609 --> 21:12.709 It's not just this. 21:12.710 --> 21:16.050 The price is lower therefore the final outcome's going to be 21:16.053 --> 21:17.473 much bigger on average. 21:17.470 --> 21:21.670 So to put it another way, if you had two possibilities 21:21.674 --> 21:24.694 which you knew were equally likely, 21:24.690 --> 21:28.880 1 half and 1 half, and the market paid off 21:28.878 --> 21:33.578 something good here and something bad here, 21:33.578 --> 21:36.288 so everybody's rich here and everybody's poor here. 21:36.288 --> 21:39.168 The price of the Arrow security of this state is going to be 21:39.172 --> 21:42.302 much lower than the price of the Arrow security of this state. 21:42.298 --> 21:45.118 So this state is going to have a price, 21:45.118 --> 21:49.138 let's say .8, and this one might have a price 21:49.136 --> 21:53.906 .2 because here the bad state, that's when everybody's poor, 21:53.906 --> 21:56.286 so you're going to, you know, this formula 21:56.288 --> 21:59.108 basically tells you that if you're paying off here you're 21:59.112 --> 22:01.232 negatively correlated with the market, 22:01.230 --> 22:03.750 you're going to have to pay a very high price for it because 22:03.752 --> 22:04.482 you're hedging. 22:04.480 --> 22:08.020 By buying this security you're balancing off what you have with 22:08.018 --> 22:08.758 the market. 22:08.759 --> 22:13.379 By buying the market, people don't like that because 22:13.375 --> 22:17.445 it adds more risk to what you already have. 22:17.450 --> 22:21.590 And so people don't like it so they're not going pay very much, 22:21.594 --> 22:25.744 so the price will be much less than the actual probability of 1 22:25.738 --> 22:26.338 half. 22:26.338 --> 22:28.048 So that's the conclusion of what we've done. 22:28.048 --> 22:30.538 I want to now connect this to Social Security. 22:30.538 --> 22:36.378 So you remember in our Social Security model we had land that 22:36.383 --> 22:40.003 went here, here, here, paid 1,1, 22:39.998 --> 22:43.798 1,1, 1, and we had these people, 22:43.798 --> 22:47.248 overlapping generations-people like that. 22:47.250 --> 22:51.020 And we discovered a very important thing. 22:51.019 --> 22:54.949 The reason why Social Security seems to be broke is because we 22:54.952 --> 22:59.082 gave away so much money to the people in the first generation. 22:59.078 --> 23:01.788 It's not that Social Security wastes money like George Bush 23:01.786 --> 23:03.836 seems to imply whenever he talks about it. 23:03.838 --> 23:05.528 It's not like they just throw it away. 23:05.528 --> 23:09.318 It's that we gave a huge gift to the people in the '40s, 23:09.317 --> 23:13.307 the '50s and the '60s and so everyone after that has to pay 23:13.309 --> 23:14.549 for that gift. 23:14.548 --> 23:19.098 But there's a little bit more to George Bush's story than I've 23:19.104 --> 23:22.394 allowed so far, which is that he wants to put 23:22.387 --> 23:24.327 the money into stocks. 23:24.328 --> 23:29.068 And we know that stocks are going to get a higher return 23:29.068 --> 23:30.188 than bonds. 23:30.190 --> 23:32.450 That's the whole point of this theory. 23:32.450 --> 23:35.160 You put money in stocks, the expected return on stocks 23:35.157 --> 23:37.507 is higher than the expected return on bonds. 23:37.509 --> 23:41.279 So if you want to make this mathematical we have to add the 23:41.276 --> 23:45.236 possibility of risk and stocks and it looks like it's going to 23:45.237 --> 23:48.797 be hopelessly complicated, but we can do it very easily. 23:48.798 --> 23:54.168 So I'm going to reproduce the same picture with uncertainty in 23:54.171 --> 23:57.571 stocks in it, and then we're going to come 23:57.574 --> 24:01.634 back to Social Security and spend 15 minutes talking about 24:01.634 --> 24:04.844 what's the right plan for Social Security. 24:04.838 --> 24:08.158 So how could I take this simple model, 24:08.160 --> 24:10.450 which already seemed complicated, it's already a 24:10.452 --> 24:13.562 pretty complicated model, had no uncertainty, 24:13.556 --> 24:16.386 and now put uncertainty in it? 24:16.390 --> 24:23.140 Well, I'm going to suppose that land--so this is the land 24:23.138 --> 24:27.718 dividends I'm now going to describe. 24:27.720 --> 24:29.460 And by the way, I had people with endowments 24:29.457 --> 24:29.737 here. 24:29.740 --> 24:31.720 They were (3,1) and (3,1). 24:31.720 --> 24:34.440 Remember, this is their endowments, but we didn't say 24:34.439 --> 24:36.269 where those endowments came from. 24:36.269 --> 24:37.819 So I'm going to take the land dividends. 24:37.818 --> 24:41.108 I'm going to suppose the dividend of the land today is 1, 24:41.107 --> 24:44.217 but things might get better or worse in the future. 24:44.220 --> 24:48.480 Maybe the dividend goes to 2 or down to 1 half, 24:48.482 --> 24:49.042 say. 24:49.038 --> 24:53.058 I'm taking some extreme case where it doubles or halves, 24:53.058 --> 24:56.898 and maybe after that it could double again or it could go back 24:56.900 --> 25:00.740 to 1 and here it could go to 1 or it could go to 1 quarter. 25:00.740 --> 25:04.010 So what dividends are doing is a random walk. 25:04.009 --> 25:08.679 If the economy starts getting more productive then it's in a 25:08.683 --> 25:11.573 better position, and from that point things get 25:11.569 --> 25:14.239 even more productive or maybe go back to where they were. 25:14.240 --> 25:16.780 If things get worse they're worse, but maybe things will 25:16.776 --> 25:19.216 start to get better again or continue to get worse. 25:19.220 --> 25:24.480 So this is what I imagine as my process of dividends. 25:24.480 --> 25:30.150 So if you own the land you get all these dividends in the whole 25:30.154 --> 25:32.814 infinite future, all right? 25:32.808 --> 25:36.218 And now let's say that there's labor as well, 25:36.215 --> 25:37.605 so labor income. 25:37.608 --> 25:41.498 So I have to make an assumption about labor income. 25:41.500 --> 25:48.390 So I'm going to assume only young work. 25:48.390 --> 25:50.570 So here we kind of made the same assumption. 25:50.568 --> 25:53.288 You get a lot when you're young and not much when you're old. 25:53.288 --> 25:55.748 I'm going to assume only the young work, 25:55.750 --> 26:01.160 and I'm going to assume that this productivity gains or 26:01.157 --> 26:02.697 losses, and by the way, 26:02.704 --> 26:04.164 you might think you never go backwards. 26:04.160 --> 26:07.470 Maybe it goes from 1 to 2 or 1 to 1.1. 26:07.470 --> 26:11.720 So it's always growing, but random. 26:11.720 --> 26:15.260 But I'm just going to keep it here since I solved this example 26:15.256 --> 26:16.006 last night. 26:16.009 --> 26:18.889 I might as well stick to that one, but there's no reason 26:18.892 --> 26:21.782 why--I could have made the thing always, no matter what, 26:21.775 --> 26:23.815 either stay the same or get better. 26:23.818 --> 26:25.878 That might have been a better example to do, 26:25.880 --> 26:29.180 more realistic because we don't really have tremendous 26:29.182 --> 26:32.692 productivity declines, but anyway, all I mean to do is 26:32.686 --> 26:34.506 to put some randomness here. 26:34.509 --> 26:42.509 So only young work and wages proportional to dividends, 26:42.509 --> 26:50.959 so let's just assume this, so I'm assuming--this is what's 26:50.955 --> 26:56.285 called neutral technical change. 26:56.288 --> 26:58.918 So presumably the reason why productivity is going up, 26:58.920 --> 27:01.210 the dividends are getting higher, is there are more 27:01.207 --> 27:03.447 discoveries improving the product of the land, 27:03.450 --> 27:05.910 but they're probably also improving the product of labor, 27:05.910 --> 27:08.380 and so let's say they have same effect on both. 27:08.380 --> 27:12.080 So I'm going to assume that labor is actually--put the 1 27:12.080 --> 27:12.620 above. 27:12.618 --> 27:20.318 Let's say labor always gets 3 times what dividends are. 27:20.318 --> 27:25.468 So this is a 6 and this will be 3 halves, and this will be 12 27:25.472 --> 27:29.772 and 3 again and 3 quarters, so that's what labor is 27:29.768 --> 27:32.258 getting, so labor income. 27:32.259 --> 27:38.039 I shouldn't have switched colors, labor income. 27:38.038 --> 27:43.368 So that's my complicated world, way more complicated than it 27:43.374 --> 27:44.554 was before. 27:44.548 --> 27:47.118 So if you own the land you get all the dividends in the future. 27:47.118 --> 27:50.678 People live two periods, so I'm going to assume that 27:50.681 --> 27:54.041 utility-- so you're going to live when 27:54.037 --> 27:58.837 you're young and then when you're old and up and when 27:58.844 --> 28:00.974 you're old and down. 28:00.970 --> 28:04.120 So you're going to live--let's say a guy born here, 28:04.121 --> 28:06.581 he's young here, or she's young here. 28:06.578 --> 28:10.028 She can work here, and then she's going to be old 28:10.032 --> 28:12.982 here and here, but when she's old it's not 28:12.983 --> 28:16.873 clear how good her investment's going to turn out. 28:16.868 --> 28:20.058 So this is going to just be our simple log. 28:20.058 --> 28:27.548 I'll call this 1 half log Y 1 quarter log Z_up 1 28:27.554 --> 28:31.634 quarter log Z_down. 28:31.630 --> 28:34.760 So you don't discount the future, let's say, 28:34.759 --> 28:37.499 you just take log of consumption today plus 28:37.500 --> 28:41.220 probability 1 half of log consumption in the up state, 28:41.220 --> 28:43.120 1 half log consumption in the down state. 28:43.118 --> 28:47.028 So the probabilities here are 1 half. 28:47.029 --> 28:50.629 These are the objective probabilities. 28:50.630 --> 28:54.000 So maybe I should have written the utility--maybe better it 28:54.000 --> 28:56.850 would have been to write the utility like that. 28:56.848 --> 29:00.778 That's what people know, what the probabilities are. 29:00.779 --> 29:01.759 So that's it. 29:01.759 --> 29:05.069 That's my set up. 29:05.069 --> 29:07.819 So what should the economy do? 29:07.819 --> 29:08.679 What should people do? 29:08.680 --> 29:13.700 You see, if you buy--if you're some person like this woman 29:13.703 --> 29:16.503 here, she could decide to hold bonds, 29:16.497 --> 29:20.737 and she could get whatever the interest rate turns out to be, 29:20.740 --> 29:22.240 which we're going to compute in a minute, 29:22.240 --> 29:25.350 or she could hold stock in which case she's going to get-- 29:25.349 --> 29:28.479 let's start her off here, maybe. 29:28.480 --> 29:31.950 She could buy land; buy stock. 29:31.950 --> 29:33.290 Now we don't know what the price is yet. 29:33.289 --> 29:34.239 We have to compute that. 29:34.240 --> 29:36.920 But if she buys the stock she'll get a dividend of 2 here 29:36.916 --> 29:39.256 and be able to sell the land for a high price, 29:39.259 --> 29:41.729 because from here on it's obviously pretty productive, 29:41.730 --> 29:45.050 better than it was back here, or she might get unlucky and 29:45.045 --> 29:47.415 the price might, you know, the dividend might be 29:47.421 --> 29:48.761 really terrible, just 1 half, 29:48.762 --> 29:51.882 and not only that but the land she sells when she's old is also 29:51.878 --> 29:53.788 going to have a really lousy price. 29:53.788 --> 29:57.058 So if she holds land she's going to get a high dividend and 29:57.060 --> 29:59.880 a high capital return, or else a low dividend and a 29:59.882 --> 30:01.182 low capital return. 30:01.180 --> 30:04.110 It's really risky for her, or she could just buy a bond at 30:04.107 --> 30:07.087 whatever interest rate it turns out to be and get something 30:07.086 --> 30:07.546 safe. 30:07.548 --> 30:12.298 So what should she do, and will that be a good thing 30:12.299 --> 30:17.799 for the economy or can we make everybody better off by using 30:17.796 --> 30:19.656 Social Security? 30:19.660 --> 30:29.560 So how can we solve this? 30:29.558 --> 30:31.988 So it looks like a really complicated model to solve 30:31.986 --> 30:34.076 because we've got a generation born here, 30:34.078 --> 30:36.628 another one born here, the same generation might be 30:36.625 --> 30:38.965 born up here under different circumstances, 30:38.970 --> 30:41.960 and then this generation here could be born under any of three 30:41.957 --> 30:47.287 different circumstances, so there's a lot to solve for. 30:47.288 --> 30:51.378 But what we know is that when we compute the Arrow price, 30:51.380 --> 30:54.640 starting from any point, this Arrow price is going to be 30:54.642 --> 30:57.962 bigger than 1 half and this one's going to be less than 1 30:57.963 --> 31:01.293 half because the economy is doing much worse down here so 31:01.286 --> 31:04.666 people know they're all going to get screwed down here and 31:04.667 --> 31:06.267 consume a lot less. 31:06.269 --> 31:08.879 So to hedge that they're all going to want to buy, 31:08.884 --> 31:12.144 they're going to be desperate to buy consumption down here. 31:12.140 --> 31:14.870 Of course they can't all do that, so it's got to be the 31:14.869 --> 31:17.949 price that's more than 1 half that discourages them from doing 31:17.953 --> 31:18.413 that. 31:18.410 --> 31:21.160 And they don't really need that much to buy up here because 31:21.159 --> 31:23.199 their dividends, they're going to be so rich 31:23.198 --> 31:23.718 anyway. 31:23.720 --> 31:27.380 So the price of the Arrow security is going to be less 31:27.383 --> 31:31.463 than 1 half because there's so much that they have to end up 31:31.460 --> 31:34.640 holding and that'll encourage them to buy. 31:34.640 --> 31:36.550 I mean, sorry, I said the logic backwards. 31:36.548 --> 31:38.638 There's so much that they're going to have to end up 31:38.641 --> 31:40.651 consuming because the economy is so productive. 31:40.650 --> 31:43.480 How can you get them to plan to consume that much up there? 31:43.480 --> 31:45.860 It's by having a low Arrow security price. 31:45.858 --> 31:48.388 So even in advance they know that they're going to end up 31:48.385 --> 31:51.045 consuming a lot and they're happy to do that because they're 31:51.048 --> 31:53.798 willing to buy Arrow securities because they're so cheap. 31:53.799 --> 31:58.339 So how do we solve all this? 31:58.338 --> 32:00.058 So everybody following the problem? 32:00.058 --> 32:02.708 It's quite a complicated problem, but it turns out to 32:02.711 --> 32:04.141 have a very simple answer. 32:04.140 --> 32:04.670 Yep? 32:04.670 --> 32:08.980 Student: So the down state, the price of consumption 32:08.980 --> 32:11.880 is high but the price of land is low? 32:11.880 --> 32:12.980 Prof: Right, so. 32:12.980 --> 32:17.690 Well, so if you start--starting from here the price of 32:17.686 --> 32:20.636 consumption-- if you want to buy at this 32:20.643 --> 32:22.833 point, consumption at this point, 32:22.828 --> 32:25.648 you're going to have to pay more than 1 half to get it, 32:25.650 --> 32:29.830 but you know that once you get here the price of land is going 32:29.827 --> 32:31.057 to have dropped. 32:31.059 --> 32:32.259 So yes, I'm agreeing with you. 32:32.259 --> 32:35.129 Student: I understand the first part because the CAPM 32:35.133 --> 32:35.623 price... 32:35.618 --> 32:37.208 Prof: Right, now why should the price of 32:37.211 --> 32:37.941 land be lower here? 32:37.940 --> 32:42.610 Remember, the price of land is always in terms of the 32:42.606 --> 32:45.386 consumption good that period. 32:45.390 --> 32:48.770 Every period I might as well take an apple to have a price of 32:48.773 --> 32:49.003 1. 32:49.000 --> 32:52.510 So you see, the land here is producing an entire apple, 32:52.505 --> 32:56.135 and on average going forward it's going to be producing 1 32:56.140 --> 32:56.790 apple. 32:56.788 --> 32:59.398 The geometric average of all these numbers is 1 starting at 32:59.404 --> 32:59.994 this point. 32:59.990 --> 33:03.590 Once you've gone down to here production has deteriorated. 33:03.588 --> 33:05.928 The land is only producing 1 half an apple here, 33:05.930 --> 33:08.290 and in the future instead of producing 12 it's going to 33:08.286 --> 33:10.726 produce 3 apples here and only 3 quarters of an apple. 33:10.730 --> 33:13.410 So it's crummier land down here, so you're going to pay 33:13.414 --> 33:14.414 less for the land. 33:14.410 --> 33:17.950 Any other questions? 33:17.950 --> 33:21.430 But I'm going to tell you exactly what you'll pay for the 33:21.433 --> 33:21.873 land. 33:21.869 --> 33:23.429 So we're going to solve this. 33:23.430 --> 33:37.980 So need to solve for land price in each state, 33:37.980 --> 33:56.370 and interest rate at each state, and price of up Arrow 33:56.365 --> 34:06.105 security, and price of down Arrow 34:06.107 --> 34:11.927 security at each state. 34:11.929 --> 34:14.109 So how can we do all that? 34:14.110 --> 34:17.230 Well, first of all you notice that the Arrow securities are 34:17.226 --> 34:18.136 always the key. 34:18.139 --> 34:21.779 Once you solve for those you can figure out everything else. 34:21.780 --> 34:28.050 So we just have to solve for these, the price of the up and 34:28.052 --> 34:32.272 down Arrow securities in every state. 34:32.268 --> 34:41.988 Oh, this was me in a previous class today. 34:41.989 --> 34:43.529 I didn't erase it. 34:43.530 --> 35:00.240 I figured the next guy would do it, serves me right. 35:00.239 --> 35:03.469 So how can we solve this? 35:03.469 --> 35:15.699 Well, we can guess, let's do it up here, 35:15.697 --> 35:27.297 guess that these prices, Arrow prices, 35:27.300 --> 35:36.080 the same at every state. 35:36.079 --> 35:38.489 So what do I mean by that? 35:38.489 --> 35:41.359 I mean, here, how many apples would you pay 35:41.358 --> 35:42.928 to get an apple here? 35:42.929 --> 35:47.409 I'm guessing that that's the same amount you would pay here 35:47.405 --> 35:49.175 to get an apple here. 35:49.179 --> 35:53.049 And what you'd pay in apples at this point to get an apple down 35:53.050 --> 35:56.980 here is going to be the same as this generation would pay to get 35:56.983 --> 35:58.423 an apple down here. 35:58.420 --> 35:59.250 That's a guess. 35:59.250 --> 36:00.770 We have to verify that that's going to work. 36:00.768 --> 36:10.158 It seems like everything is sort of homogeneous, 36:10.161 --> 36:22.551 and so guess that price of land is proportional to dividends in 36:22.552 --> 36:25.552 that state. 36:25.550 --> 36:28.240 Well, the whole thing is sort of homogeneous and everything, 36:28.239 --> 36:32.489 so if the land here is 4 times as good as the land here, 36:32.489 --> 36:36.119 the land here is 4 times as good as the land here, 36:36.119 --> 36:39.339 because the dividends are always 4 times higher if you go 36:39.338 --> 36:40.198 up one thing. 36:40.199 --> 36:42.579 So this is 4 times that, that's 4 times that. 36:42.579 --> 36:46.499 So why not guess that the price of land is 4 times here than it 36:46.503 --> 36:49.483 is here, 4 times higher here than it is here. 36:49.480 --> 36:51.320 Sounds possible, anyway, and of course these are 36:51.322 --> 36:52.972 going to turn out to be correct guesses. 36:52.969 --> 36:57.729 So once you make these guesses it's going to be very simple to 36:57.728 --> 37:01.788 find the equilibrium, and then we can verify that the 37:01.786 --> 37:03.656 guesses are correct. 37:03.659 --> 37:07.389 So what does this guy want to do here? 37:07.389 --> 37:09.409 So assume you only work when you're young. 37:09.409 --> 37:10.559 So what's your income? 37:10.559 --> 37:13.639 What's anybody's income like this young guy here? 37:13.639 --> 37:19.749 Young at time 1, so this is time 1 here, 37:19.746 --> 37:26.156 time 2, time 3, time 4, so at time 1 their 37:26.164 --> 37:34.154 income is 3 because that's what their wage was. 37:34.150 --> 37:37.590 They work when they're young and they've got three. 37:37.590 --> 37:38.090 That's it. 37:38.090 --> 37:39.460 They don't own the land when they're born. 37:39.460 --> 37:42.760 They're going to buy the land but they don't own it now, 37:42.760 --> 37:44.740 and so what do they want to do? 37:44.739 --> 37:46.789 They want to consume when they're young, 37:46.786 --> 37:48.146 their utility, remember? 37:48.150 --> 37:51.030 So what's their budget set? 37:51.030 --> 37:55.540 Their budget set is they can consume Y, that's consuming 37:55.543 --> 37:58.913 here, or they can consume here or here. 37:58.909 --> 38:03.139 So they can consume P_up times 38:03.135 --> 38:09.305 Z_up P_down times Z_down. 38:09.309 --> 38:12.289 That's what they can do with those Arrow securities. 38:12.289 --> 38:15.529 So what are they trying to maximize? 38:15.530 --> 38:22.800 They're trying to maximize 1 half log Y 1 quarter log 38:22.798 --> 38:29.508 Z_up 1 quarter log Z_down. 38:29.510 --> 38:32.180 That's what they're trying to do. 38:32.179 --> 38:34.619 So what do we have to do? 38:34.619 --> 38:37.979 We have to clear this market and this market given what the 38:37.980 --> 38:40.530 young are going to do in the next period, 38:40.530 --> 38:43.030 but let's see what this guy's going to do when he's young. 38:43.030 --> 38:46.360 Everybody is going to face a similar, basically a scaled up 38:46.358 --> 38:47.848 version of this problem. 38:47.849 --> 38:49.659 So this is what the guy is doing here. 38:49.659 --> 38:52.909 He's got an income of 3 and there's the price of up and down 38:52.911 --> 38:53.961 Arrow securities. 38:53.960 --> 38:57.700 That's going to tell him what to consume here and what to plan 38:57.695 --> 38:59.835 to consume up here and down here. 38:59.840 --> 39:01.690 Student: Do you change your utility function? 39:01.690 --> 39:03.350 Prof: So utility function is the same one as 39:03.347 --> 39:03.577 this. 39:03.579 --> 39:06.639 I just multiplied through by 1 half, right? 39:06.639 --> 39:09.679 So I put 1 half, 1 quarter, 1 quarter to get 39:09.684 --> 39:10.184 that. 39:10.179 --> 39:14.229 So I've just multiplied it all by a constant. 39:14.230 --> 39:16.470 So now the coefficients add up to 1; 39:16.469 --> 39:18.039 1 half, 1 quarter and 1 quarter. 39:18.039 --> 39:20.619 That's his budget constraint, but what's the budget 39:20.619 --> 39:22.889 constraint going to be of a guy down here? 39:22.889 --> 39:24.179 It's exactly the same. 39:24.179 --> 39:28.079 He's going to maximize the same utility function and his budget 39:28.079 --> 39:30.419 constraint, since the prices of the Arrow 39:30.420 --> 39:34.050 securities are the same, the only difference is going to 39:34.045 --> 39:36.805 be that he's only got 3 halves here. 39:36.809 --> 39:39.079 So they're pretty similar problems. 39:39.079 --> 39:41.829 So let's see what the guy at time 1 is going to do. 39:41.829 --> 39:49.029 That's going to imply that Y = (Cobb-Douglas) 1 half times (his 39:49.030 --> 39:55.420 income) 3 divided by the price of Y which is just 1, 39:55.420 --> 40:03.110 so 1 half of 3 over 1 which is 3 halves. 40:03.110 --> 40:06.750 And what's he going do when he's old? 40:06.750 --> 40:09.740 Z_up is going to be--well, 40:09.739 --> 40:15.029 his Cobb-Douglas is 1 quarter, and then his income is still 3, 40:15.030 --> 40:18.240 and then the price is P_up of the Arrow 40:18.242 --> 40:18.982 security. 40:18.980 --> 40:26.110 In the down case he's going to have 1 quarter times 3 (that's 40:26.114 --> 40:31.114 his income) divided by P_down. 40:31.110 --> 40:33.950 So to clear this market what do we have to do? 40:33.949 --> 40:37.379 We have to clear the market by doing what? 40:37.380 --> 40:40.100 Z_up, that's this guy, 40:40.096 --> 40:44.906 so 1 quarter (so this is the old guy) times 3 divided by 40:44.914 --> 40:46.584 P_up. 40:46.579 --> 40:49.419 That's what this guy wants to consume up here, 40:49.422 --> 40:53.092 plus what the young are going to do there, but we know what 40:53.088 --> 40:55.298 the young are going to do here. 40:55.300 --> 40:58.740 This young person is doing exactly what this guy did, 40:58.739 --> 41:02.379 except instead of having a starting wealth of 3 he has a 41:02.376 --> 41:04.026 starting wealth of 6. 41:04.030 --> 41:07.550 So instead of consuming young 3 halves he's going to consume 41:07.554 --> 41:08.574 young 6 halves. 41:08.570 --> 41:12.450 So this is going to be plus 3. 41:12.449 --> 41:15.679 He's going to consume half of his wages just like this guy 41:15.682 --> 41:18.352 consumed half of his wages when he was young. 41:18.349 --> 41:21.409 So this new young guy, the young guys are always going 41:21.409 --> 41:24.989 to consume in the first period half of what their wages are. 41:24.989 --> 41:26.679 That's what this equation tells us. 41:26.679 --> 41:29.189 If this is your budget set, this is your income, 41:29.192 --> 41:32.082 this is what your budget set is and this is what you're 41:32.077 --> 41:32.877 maximizing. 41:32.880 --> 41:36.180 This is a very special Cobb-Douglas case where you have 41:36.182 --> 41:40.132 endowments only in one good, so it's clear that in that good 41:40.134 --> 41:43.384 you'll always consume the Cobb-Douglas coefficient 41:43.380 --> 41:47.210 fraction of it, 1 half of that, so 3 halves. 41:47.210 --> 41:52.210 And this guy's going to consume 1 half of 6 which is 3. 41:52.210 --> 41:55.800 So the old up here are going to consume that number. 41:55.800 --> 42:03.400 The young are going to consume 3, and what's the total that's 42:03.403 --> 42:07.463 available for them to consume? 42:07.460 --> 42:08.640 What's available? 42:08.639 --> 42:10.729 Student: 6. 42:10.730 --> 42:12.940 Prof: No, more. 42:12.940 --> 42:13.990 Student: 8. 42:13.989 --> 42:17.879 Prof: 8; the young got 6 apples and the 42:17.884 --> 42:24.444 land paid 2 apples in dividends, so the total number of apples 42:24.440 --> 42:25.300 is 8. 42:25.300 --> 42:26.650 So that's it. 42:26.650 --> 42:31.690 And so we can solve that and that's going to imply that 42:31.690 --> 42:36.800 multiplying-- so that's 5 and multiplying by 42:36.795 --> 42:39.405 4 is 20, so P_U, 42:39.414 --> 42:42.844 of course I'm going to screw this up now. 42:42.840 --> 42:48.560 P_U is 3 over 20, because if you put 3 over 20 in 42:48.563 --> 42:54.783 here you get the 3s cancel and you get 20 over 4 which is 5, 42:54.780 --> 42:57.860 and 5 3 is 8, so it's 3 over 20. 42:57.860 --> 43:00.430 Now meanwhile, what are we going to have in 43:00.431 --> 43:01.351 the up state? 43:01.349 --> 43:02.729 In the up state... 43:02.730 --> 43:03.480 Student: In the down state. 43:03.480 --> 43:04.020 Prof: Down state. 43:04.019 --> 43:05.369 That was the up state. 43:05.369 --> 43:13.749 In the down state the guy's going to do 1 quarter 3 over 43:13.751 --> 43:16.191 P_D. 43:16.190 --> 43:18.150 What is this other guy going to do? 43:18.150 --> 43:24.250 The young person here is going to consume what? 43:24.250 --> 43:26.060 So in the downstate what are we going to have? 43:26.059 --> 43:31.069 The equation of the downstate is going to be-- 43:31.070 --> 43:38.150 so this one 1 quarter 3 divided by P_down plus what's 43:38.152 --> 43:43.182 this guy going to consume when he's young? 43:43.179 --> 43:47.169 Well, his income, his wages are 3 halves and he's 43:47.168 --> 43:51.488 going to consume half of that so it's 3 quarters, 43:51.489 --> 43:54.149 right, because when you're young you always end up 43:54.150 --> 43:57.800 consuming half of your wages, so 3 quarters and that has to 43:57.802 --> 44:03.892 equal-- what's the total? 44:03.889 --> 44:07.879 2? 44:07.880 --> 44:11.680 2, so what does that leave us? 44:11.679 --> 44:15.449 That leaves us 3 quarters, that's 5 fourths, 44:15.452 --> 44:16.772 so let's see. 44:16.768 --> 44:22.588 So 5 fourths equals 3 quarters over P_D, 44:22.590 --> 44:30.380 so P_D is going to equal 3 fifths, 44:30.380 --> 44:32.840 right, because the 4s drop out and you put P_D up and 44:32.842 --> 44:34.432 the 5 down, it's 3 fifths. 44:34.429 --> 44:35.279 So that's it. 44:35.280 --> 44:37.790 So now we've got--we've figured out the prices. 44:37.789 --> 44:39.929 So this Arrow security was 1 half. 44:39.929 --> 44:42.229 I mean, the probabilities are 1 half, 1 half, 44:42.228 --> 44:44.368 but the prices, the Arrow security prices, 44:44.369 --> 44:47.399 are going to be less than 1 half and more than 1 half. 44:47.400 --> 44:52.420 I forgot what they were already, 3 twentieths, 44:52.420 --> 44:55.210 3 over 20 and 3 over 5. 44:55.210 --> 44:56.510 Those are the Arrow prices. 44:56.510 --> 44:58.610 By the way, you notice they don't add up to 1. 44:58.610 --> 45:03.510 So what's the interest rate? 45:03.510 --> 45:07.010 So if you want to get--a riskless bond pays 1 in each of 45:07.014 --> 45:09.964 these two states, so how much is that worth, 45:09.963 --> 45:13.833 1 over (1 r) equals (You have to buy both Arrow securities. 45:13.829 --> 45:15.089 We've done this before.) 45:15.090 --> 45:20.740 3 twentieths 3 fifths which equals 15 twentieths, 45:20.737 --> 45:27.087 which equals 3 fourths, so therefore 1 r = 4 thirds. 45:27.090 --> 45:30.550 So r is 33 percent. 45:30.550 --> 45:31.950 So that's what we did. 45:31.949 --> 45:36.349 We've got the probabilities, 3 twentieths and 3 fifths. 45:36.349 --> 45:39.179 Just as we thought the price of the down Arrow security is going 45:39.177 --> 45:41.907 to be much bigger than the price of the up Arrow security even 45:41.914 --> 45:44.254 though objectively they have 50/50 probability, 45:44.250 --> 45:45.550 and why is that? 45:45.550 --> 45:49.030 Because everyone who's rational is going to realize that they 45:49.034 --> 45:52.524 have to plan to consume much more up here than down here, 45:52.518 --> 45:56.628 but they're not going to want to do that unless the price is 45:56.634 --> 45:57.684 much cheaper. 45:57.679 --> 45:59.099 So that's how we got the price. 45:59.099 --> 46:00.749 So now what's the price of land? 46:00.750 --> 46:03.760 That's the only last thing we have to figure out, 46:03.764 --> 46:05.214 so the price of land. 46:05.210 --> 46:11.920 So the price of land at time 1 equals what? 46:11.920 --> 46:14.510 Well, what if you buy the land? 46:14.510 --> 46:17.510 What do you get? 46:17.510 --> 46:23.460 You get 3 twentieths, then you get the dividend which 46:23.458 --> 46:28.838 is 2, but then you get to sell the land which is 46:28.835 --> 46:31.805 P_land^(up). 46:31.809 --> 46:36.169 And then plus if you get the down state you get a 46:36.172 --> 46:40.902 dividend--so the down state is worth 3 fifths to you, 46:40.900 --> 46:41.810 right? 46:41.809 --> 46:43.289 And then what do you get? 46:43.289 --> 46:46.309 What's your dividend? 46:46.309 --> 46:52.329 1 half the price of the land you can sell, 46:52.331 --> 46:56.151 P_land^(down). 46:56.150 --> 46:59.440 So that's what the price of land is at 1. 46:59.440 --> 47:02.000 It depends, of course, on what you can sell the price 47:02.001 --> 47:06.341 of land for in the future, but we made a guess here that 47:06.338 --> 47:12.058 the price of land is just proportional to the price of the 47:12.056 --> 47:13.256 dividend. 47:13.260 --> 47:16.200 So whatever the price of land is here when the dividend is 1 47:16.204 --> 47:19.004 it should be twice as high here and half as high here. 47:19.000 --> 47:21.760 So therefore this, instead of looking at it as the 47:21.764 --> 47:25.324 price of land went up it's going to be twice the price that land 47:25.317 --> 47:27.007 was at the very beginning. 47:27.010 --> 47:30.440 So it's just 2 times the price of land at the very beginning 47:30.443 --> 47:31.843 times that same price. 47:31.840 --> 47:35.870 And this price of land at down, the dividend is half, 47:35.869 --> 47:38.499 so the land is sort of half as good from here on out as it was 47:38.498 --> 47:42.498 in the beginning, so let's guess the price of 47:42.496 --> 47:47.836 land is half of what it was at the beginning. 47:47.840 --> 47:50.890 But now you see we've just got P_land in terms of 47:50.891 --> 47:53.051 other stuff and so we can solve for it. 47:53.050 --> 47:57.250 So the price of land is going to equal--well, 47:57.246 --> 47:59.436 now it's complicated. 47:59.440 --> 48:08.800 So 3 tenths 3 tenths times the price of land 3 tenths 3 tenths 48:08.800 --> 48:17.090 times the price of land, and so that means the price of 48:17.086 --> 48:20.766 land minus 6 tenths. 48:20.768 --> 48:30.838 So 4 tenths the price of land is going to equal 6 tenths. 48:30.840 --> 48:38.200 So the price of land is 3 halves at the beginning. 48:38.199 --> 48:40.529 So we figured out the price of land here. 48:40.530 --> 48:45.850 Price of land is 3 halves at the very beginning. 48:45.849 --> 48:48.349 So we've solved for the whole equilibrium. 48:48.349 --> 48:51.239 It took a long time, but I'm at the end of this 48:51.244 --> 48:52.004 story now. 48:52.000 --> 48:54.710 So let's just review what we did. 48:54.710 --> 48:58.810 And so I don't think it's that complicated a story. 48:58.809 --> 49:03.279 The story is that you've got land which has risky dividends. 49:03.280 --> 49:07.180 So instead of having one straight line of what can happen 49:07.179 --> 49:11.149 in the future we've got this infinitely expanding tree. 49:11.150 --> 49:14.780 So it's very hard to imagine solving it, but then we've built 49:14.775 --> 49:16.825 in somewhat special assumptions. 49:16.829 --> 49:19.829 We've got all this homogeneity and that allows us to solve it 49:19.833 --> 49:22.793 because it's the same problem getting repeated over and over 49:22.789 --> 49:24.969 again, just like we did before. 49:24.969 --> 49:27.679 So the price of land turns out to be 3 halves. 49:27.679 --> 49:31.549 So what is this guy going to do? 49:31.550 --> 49:36.010 He's going to take his land, his income which is 3, 49:36.010 --> 49:38.320 eat half of it, which was 3 halves, 49:38.320 --> 49:40.360 that's what we said he always does when he's young, 49:40.360 --> 49:43.910 spend half his income on consumption, 49:43.909 --> 49:47.489 the rest of his income, 3 halves, he uses to buy all 49:47.487 --> 49:48.257 the land. 49:48.260 --> 49:52.510 Now, with the land he gets a payoff of 2, but he gets to sell 49:52.507 --> 49:55.767 the land now for double the price he bought it, 49:55.766 --> 49:56.966 namely for 3. 49:56.969 --> 50:01.879 So 2 3 is 5 and that, by the way, the price of up was 50:01.880 --> 50:06.090 3 twentieths so this is 5, right, because if I put in 3 50:06.094 --> 50:08.734 twentieths up here that's the Arrow price of up, 50:08.730 --> 50:10.220 then Z_up is going to be 5. 50:10.219 --> 50:11.769 And so that's exactly how we got it. 50:11.768 --> 50:14.198 With the land he gets the dividend of 2 plus he sells the 50:14.204 --> 50:14.774 land for 3. 50:14.769 --> 50:16.489 That's 5, so he does consume 5. 50:16.489 --> 50:18.519 Z_down, incidentally, 50:18.523 --> 50:20.763 the price of down was 3 fifths. 50:20.760 --> 50:25.430 So the consumption of down--what's consumption of down 50:25.427 --> 50:26.657 going to be? 50:26.659 --> 50:29.109 Student: 5 fourths. 50:29.110 --> 50:30.530 Prof: 5 fourths, thank you. 50:30.530 --> 50:33.090 That'll be 5 fourths, so let's see that that's going 50:33.094 --> 50:34.004 to work out too. 50:34.000 --> 50:38.930 So the guy buys the land, he gets his dividend of 1 half, 50:38.929 --> 50:42.419 and then he sells the land for half of this price which is 3 50:42.420 --> 50:44.770 quarters, and 1 half plus 3 quarters is 5 50:44.769 --> 50:46.359 fourths, exactly what he's supposed to 50:46.360 --> 50:46.580 have. 50:46.579 --> 50:49.269 So you see it works out that everybody's doing exactly what 50:49.273 --> 50:51.833 they're supposed to and all the markets are clearing. 50:51.829 --> 50:55.079 Anyhow, the point is not so much the numbers, 50:55.077 --> 50:58.377 the point is the following; that sure enough, 50:58.380 --> 51:01.530 just as we said before, the price of Arrow securities 51:01.532 --> 51:04.572 are going to be expensive when things are going down and cheap 51:04.567 --> 51:05.957 when things are going up. 51:05.960 --> 51:09.640 The upshot of that is the return on stocks, 51:09.644 --> 51:12.984 like land, is going to be very high. 51:12.980 --> 51:16.870 You put in 3 halves and what happens with the 3 halves? 51:16.869 --> 51:21.219 With probability 1 half, that's what you put in, 51:21.224 --> 51:26.974 with probability 1 half you get 2 plus you get to sell the land 51:26.971 --> 51:29.011 for 3, which is 5. 51:29.010 --> 51:33.440 And with the other probability 1 half you get--the dividend is 51:33.442 --> 51:36.932 1 half, plus you sell the land for 3 quarters. 51:36.929 --> 51:39.159 That's what you're eating, 5 and 5 fourths. 51:39.159 --> 51:48.079 That's equal to 5 halves 5 fourths 5--I don't know what 51:48.077 --> 51:49.727 this is. 51:49.730 --> 51:51.120 What is this? 51:51.119 --> 51:54.619 1 half 3 quarters is 5 fourths times 1 half... 51:54.619 --> 51:55.069 Student: 5 eighths. 51:55.070 --> 51:57.730 Prof: It's 5 eighths divided by 3 halves. 51:57.730 --> 51:59.250 So this is a very high number. 51:59.250 --> 52:00.400 So what is this? 52:00.400 --> 52:06.410 4 times that, that's 25 over 8 divided by 3 52:06.414 --> 52:09.284 over 2 which is... 52:09.280 --> 52:11.180 Student: 25 over 12. 52:11.179 --> 52:11.719 Prof: Is what? 52:11.719 --> 52:13.679 Student: 25 over 12. 52:13.679 --> 52:15.359 Prof: 25 over 12, is that what you said? 52:15.360 --> 52:16.870 Student: 25 over 12. 52:16.869 --> 52:19.799 Prof: 25 over 12, I'm just believing you now. 52:19.800 --> 52:23.080 So that is over 200%, right? 52:23.079 --> 52:25.099 So your return is 100%. 52:25.099 --> 52:28.509 Whatever you put in you've more than doubled your money in 52:28.510 --> 52:30.780 expectation, whereas the interest rate, 52:30.784 --> 52:33.184 we said, was 33 and 1 third percent. 52:33.179 --> 52:35.889 So of course you're getting a tremendous return by putting 52:35.891 --> 52:38.751 your money into capital because that's the whole point of the 52:38.746 --> 52:39.266 theory. 52:39.269 --> 52:40.609 It's risky. 52:40.610 --> 52:43.430 The whole economy is going to be rich or poor together, 52:43.429 --> 52:46.299 so the price of capital, on the margin it's a very risky 52:46.304 --> 52:47.144 thing to do. 52:47.139 --> 52:50.259 It just adds to this inequality in your consumption. 52:50.260 --> 52:51.620 So the price is going to be low. 52:51.619 --> 52:53.529 You're going to get a very high return. 52:53.530 --> 52:54.920 That's all I wanted to do. 52:54.920 --> 52:58.460 I just solved it out concretely so you can see very clearly that 52:58.458 --> 53:01.098 you get a high return in the good state and-- 53:01.099 --> 53:03.369 you get a high return on capital, much higher than the 53:03.369 --> 53:04.569 riskless rate of interest. 53:04.570 --> 53:05.310 So there we are. 53:05.309 --> 53:08.429 We're back at the beginning now where George Bush--we can see 53:08.434 --> 53:11.044 that somewhere in the middle here things are really 53:11.038 --> 53:11.818 disastrous. 53:11.820 --> 53:14.150 These people who are getting Social Security, 53:14.150 --> 53:18.050 which means they're getting a fixed amount here and here are 53:18.045 --> 53:21.185 doing really badly, at least in expected return, 53:21.190 --> 53:24.330 compared to what they would do in the stock market. 53:24.329 --> 53:30.939 And so what should we do about that, and is it true that just 53:30.940 --> 53:37.440 because stocks make a higher return, we should privatize? 53:37.440 --> 53:38.410 So what do you think now? 53:38.409 --> 53:40.169 Where are we in this argument? 53:40.170 --> 53:47.110 Has anything materially changed? 53:47.110 --> 53:50.610 So George Bush is saying, and many Republicans say, 53:50.614 --> 53:54.544 that we should let people, you know, get them invested in 53:54.539 --> 53:55.309 stocks. 53:55.309 --> 53:57.659 There's a higher expected return. 53:57.659 --> 54:10.479 So what do we think about that? 54:10.480 --> 54:23.820 What do you think about that? 54:23.820 --> 54:25.910 This is a real policy issue here. 54:25.909 --> 54:27.239 We've got this problem in America. 54:27.239 --> 54:31.429 Right now we've got this huge deficit in Social Security. 54:31.429 --> 54:34.899 The rate of return has gotten really poor for your generation. 54:34.900 --> 54:37.550 You're looking forward to not making very much money, 54:37.550 --> 54:40.590 and now we know theoretically, confirming what we've seen in 54:40.590 --> 54:42.910 the past, stocks are making higher 54:42.905 --> 54:47.805 returns than bonds, and Social Security is paying 54:47.811 --> 54:53.121 people a fraction of the wages of the young. 54:53.119 --> 54:56.499 So let me remind you of the arguments. 54:56.500 --> 55:00.140 So the issue has come up because Social Security is 55:00.135 --> 55:01.805 running out of money. 55:01.809 --> 55:03.779 So it came up because of this problem. 55:03.780 --> 55:05.240 There's going to be a deficit. 55:05.239 --> 55:08.269 If we continue to pay people at the same rules that we've used 55:08.266 --> 55:11.336 up until now we're not going to be able to afford to do it much 55:11.344 --> 55:13.744 longer, so we're going to have to lower 55:13.742 --> 55:16.012 what we pay the people going forward, 55:16.010 --> 55:19.960 lower it in some clever way like they don't get money until 55:19.960 --> 55:21.050 they're older. 55:21.050 --> 55:24.360 Instead of 65 make them wait until 70, or do something like 55:24.360 --> 55:25.730 that to pay them less. 55:25.730 --> 55:27.680 That's one way of balancing things. 55:27.679 --> 55:30.439 And because we're going to have to make changes like that, 55:30.440 --> 55:33.060 that's why the whole issue of Social Security has come up, 55:33.059 --> 55:37.399 and now deeper thinkers are questioning the whole idea of 55:37.402 --> 55:38.802 Social Security. 55:38.800 --> 55:42.220 So let me just remind you that America was ahead of everyone in 55:42.215 --> 55:45.515 the world when we created Social Security under Roosevelt. 55:45.519 --> 55:47.229 Nobody had anything like it. 55:47.230 --> 55:50.670 Then everybody in the rest of the world gradually copied us, 55:50.670 --> 55:54.040 and now everybody's facing the same problem we are, 55:54.039 --> 55:55.689 which we know why you have to face it. 55:55.690 --> 55:59.280 You're giving away stuff to the people at the beginning and so 55:59.284 --> 56:02.704 they're facing it by changing Social Security in some crazy 56:02.701 --> 56:05.351 way or another, and we haven't changed anything 56:05.351 --> 56:06.831 at all, but obviously we have to, 56:06.829 --> 56:09.229 and the question is how should we change it and what's the 56:09.226 --> 56:10.106 right thing to do. 56:10.110 --> 56:13.020 And just to remind you, again, of the issues, 56:13.023 --> 56:16.873 the Democrats and Republicans seem to be totally opposed to 56:16.865 --> 56:17.855 each other. 56:17.860 --> 56:21.950 The Democrats say, "Oh, we want to continue to give 56:21.945 --> 56:27.025 people who have done poorly in their lives a better deal on 56:27.030 --> 56:31.500 Social Security because we want to redistribute. 56:31.500 --> 56:32.970 We want to help the poor." 56:32.969 --> 56:34.969 The Republicans, actually some of them agree 56:34.965 --> 56:36.725 with that, but some of them don't agree 56:36.731 --> 56:38.741 with that, but anyway, even the ones who 56:38.737 --> 56:41.697 agree that's not the most important thing they think of in 56:41.702 --> 56:42.692 Social Security. 56:42.690 --> 56:45.980 Then the Democrats say, "Social Security is so 56:45.978 --> 56:49.858 important because we're sharing risks across generations. 56:49.860 --> 56:55.830 If the next generation has poor wages so they end up down here 56:55.827 --> 56:59.207 with bad wages, you know, the economy takes a 56:59.206 --> 57:02.326 turn south with bad wages, then the old people should 57:02.329 --> 57:03.769 suffer along with them. 57:03.768 --> 57:06.888 And if the young do better with high wages because things went 57:06.889 --> 57:09.599 up then the old should also get better Social Security 57:09.601 --> 57:11.801 dividends," and that's what the current 57:11.800 --> 57:13.080 situation promises. 57:13.079 --> 57:17.439 It's also indexed according to inflation, all right, 57:17.440 --> 57:22.400 so once you retire then you're protected against changes in 57:22.402 --> 57:23.602 inflation. 57:23.599 --> 57:25.309 And then another important thing of Democrats, 57:25.313 --> 57:27.223 you don't have an opportunity to make a mistake. 57:27.219 --> 57:29.949 If you invest in stocks and stuff like that and the stock 57:29.945 --> 57:32.765 market suddenly collapses you're not going to lose money in 57:32.766 --> 57:35.736 Social Security because Social Security depends on the wage of 57:35.735 --> 57:38.955 the next generation, and that moves much slower than 57:38.960 --> 57:39.640 the stock. 57:39.639 --> 57:41.329 The Republicans, on the other hand, 57:41.329 --> 57:43.069 say, "This is just terrible. 57:43.070 --> 57:45.630 Nobody knows what their property rights are in Social 57:45.628 --> 57:46.168 Security. 57:46.170 --> 57:48.550 No one actually understands how much money they're getting when 57:48.552 --> 57:49.092 they're old. 57:49.090 --> 57:52.170 They just know now it's going to be bad compared to what 57:52.168 --> 57:55.248 they're paying in taxes, but you don't even know what it 57:55.248 --> 57:57.038 is, so how can that be good? 57:57.039 --> 58:00.169 It's not transparent, but not only that, 58:00.170 --> 58:02.720 whatever you think it is now it's going to turn out to be 58:02.719 --> 58:05.179 worse because in ten years somebody's going to say, 58:05.179 --> 58:06.489 'Oh, the system's not balanced. 58:06.489 --> 58:09.909 We have to delay benefits or something to put it back into 58:09.909 --> 58:11.719 balance, and we're going to take away 58:11.719 --> 58:13.689 what you thought you were going to get.'" 58:13.690 --> 58:15.240 So Republicans say, "That's horrible. 58:15.239 --> 58:18.279 Nobody knows really exactly what it is, and they get an idea 58:18.280 --> 58:20.760 of what it might be, but it could always be taken 58:20.755 --> 58:21.215 away. 58:21.219 --> 58:24.159 Really what they want to know is, 'What's the value of my 58:24.159 --> 58:26.889 Social Security account, and I want it to be mine. 58:26.889 --> 58:30.339 I can also then tell what the redistribution is. 58:30.340 --> 58:33.460 If I know what I'm paying in taxes and I know the value of 58:33.463 --> 58:36.813 the benefits I'm getting I can see that my taxes are much more 58:36.807 --> 58:37.957 than my benefits. 58:37.960 --> 58:40.830 And if I happen to be a nice guy and think it's a good idea 58:40.833 --> 58:42.373 to have redistribution, fine. 58:42.369 --> 58:44.229 But if I'm a bad, you know, not a bad guy, 58:44.230 --> 58:46.490 if I just don't believe in that much redistribution I should be 58:46.492 --> 58:48.722 aware of it and have the chance to vote against it.'" 58:48.719 --> 58:53.029 Also, a key thing is these Republicans say, 58:53.030 --> 58:55.050 "People should get equity like returns, 58:55.050 --> 58:57.360 not this wages of the next generation, 58:57.360 --> 58:58.630 those grow slowly. 58:58.630 --> 59:01.530 Stocks might have a much higher return on average. 59:01.530 --> 59:04.240 People should get equity like return, so let's put them in the 59:04.244 --> 59:05.184 stock market." 59:05.179 --> 59:07.869 And then Republicans think choice is always great. 59:07.869 --> 59:10.369 Even if people make mistakes it's their own mistake, 59:10.367 --> 59:11.737 so let them make mistakes. 59:11.739 --> 59:14.449 So those are the opposite sides of the argument. 59:14.449 --> 59:18.429 They seem totally at odds with each other and impossible to 59:18.434 --> 59:19.264 reconcile. 59:19.260 --> 59:22.090 So I want to now tell you my plan. 59:22.090 --> 59:24.660 So everyone's got the problem straight. 59:24.659 --> 59:28.209 We're running out of money and the philosophies of the two 59:28.208 --> 59:31.568 groups seem to be totally opposed, so what should we do 59:31.570 --> 59:32.380 about it? 59:32.380 --> 59:36.820 All right, so my plan, in five minutes because I want 59:36.818 --> 59:41.338 to end with Black-Scholes, my plan in five minutes is, 59:41.340 --> 59:44.500 okay, to make a few observations. 59:44.500 --> 59:47.460 First of all, yes it's true that you get a 59:47.463 --> 59:50.723 higher return on stocks than you get on bonds, 59:50.717 --> 59:52.957 but you face a higher risk. 59:52.960 --> 59:54.830 So it's not like you get it for free. 59:54.829 --> 59:56.739 It's a bigger risk. 59:56.739 --> 59:59.679 So that's number one. 59:59.679 --> 1:00:02.719 So no, actually, point zero is you've still got 1:00:02.721 --> 1:00:06.691 the problem because you gave money to all those people in the 1:00:06.688 --> 1:00:08.048 '40s, and the '50s, 1:00:08.052 --> 1:00:09.572 and the '60s, and the '70s. 1:00:09.570 --> 1:00:10.600 That money is gone. 1:00:10.599 --> 1:00:13.859 We've essentially borrowed to give them money and somebody's 1:00:13.860 --> 1:00:15.410 got to pay back that debt. 1:00:15.409 --> 1:00:17.229 And so there's no way around that. 1:00:17.230 --> 1:00:20.550 There's this huge 17 trillion dollar debt hanging out there 1:00:20.552 --> 1:00:23.822 that we have to pay back and you can't get around that. 1:00:23.820 --> 1:00:26.010 So putting the money into equities, or wherever you put 1:00:26.005 --> 1:00:27.905 the money there's still that tremendous debt. 1:00:27.909 --> 1:00:30.509 Now the question is--so you can't just make the problem go 1:00:30.514 --> 1:00:32.894 away by saying that equities have a higher return. 1:00:32.889 --> 1:00:36.389 Bonds also have a higher return than the return people are 1:00:36.387 --> 1:00:39.637 getting on Social Security because the Social Security 1:00:39.641 --> 1:00:43.321 return includes the tax that you're paying to make up for the 1:00:43.324 --> 1:00:44.924 original generation. 1:00:44.920 --> 1:00:47.520 So that's the first thing. 1:00:47.518 --> 1:00:53.368 So the next thing is maybe it's not such a big difference, 1:00:53.369 --> 1:00:58.549 this equities and not equities, because notice in this model 1:00:58.547 --> 1:01:02.697 when the stock is paying higher, when the stock dividends are 1:01:02.702 --> 1:01:04.082 higher, 2 instead of 1, 1:01:04.079 --> 1:01:06.069 the price of stocks goes up. 1:01:06.070 --> 1:01:08.440 That's a great return from the stock market, 1:01:08.436 --> 1:01:10.966 but the wages were also higher here as well. 1:01:10.969 --> 1:01:14.549 So in fact I claim that in the long run, 1:01:14.550 --> 1:01:17.040 and it's amazing that the Republicans haven't noticed 1:01:17.036 --> 1:01:19.426 this, in the long run over 30 or 40 1:01:19.434 --> 1:01:23.124 years it's obvious that the stock market and wages are 1:01:23.117 --> 1:01:24.087 correlated. 1:01:24.090 --> 1:01:27.990 I mean, if the stock market collapses that's disaster for 1:01:27.990 --> 1:01:32.520 America and you can be sure the wages are going to go down too. 1:01:32.518 --> 1:01:35.388 If our stock market's booming and America's incredibly 1:01:35.389 --> 1:01:38.479 successful it's a sure thing that in 40 years if the stock 1:01:38.478 --> 1:01:41.668 market is just booming along wages are going to be higher as 1:01:41.673 --> 1:01:42.273 well. 1:01:42.268 --> 1:01:46.768 So if you get the wages of the generation 30 years from now in 1:01:46.773 --> 1:01:50.763 the Democratic plan you're actually getting equity like 1:01:50.760 --> 1:01:53.870 returns, but you're getting an advantage 1:01:53.867 --> 1:01:56.427 which is that the wages move slowly. 1:01:56.429 --> 1:01:59.609 So although the stocks are bouncing up and down, 1:01:59.610 --> 1:02:03.660 so somebody who retires in the year 2007 if he held stock and 1:02:03.657 --> 1:02:07.367 sold it when he retired he could get a huge pension, 1:02:07.369 --> 1:02:10.789 where someone who retired in 2008 and sold the stock just 1:02:10.788 --> 1:02:14.388 when he retired he would be crushed because the stock market 1:02:14.389 --> 1:02:15.609 lost 50 percent. 1:02:15.610 --> 1:02:18.630 So that will never happen if you just pay according to wages 1:02:18.628 --> 1:02:20.418 because they're much more stable. 1:02:20.420 --> 1:02:23.730 But wages in the long run are correlated with stocks in the 1:02:23.731 --> 1:02:24.361 long run. 1:02:24.360 --> 1:02:26.690 In the short run they just don't fluctuate at much. 1:02:26.690 --> 1:02:29.340 So what is my plan? 1:02:29.340 --> 1:02:31.750 So those are just some preliminary observations and 1:02:31.746 --> 1:02:32.946 I'll give you the plan. 1:02:32.949 --> 1:02:35.339 Then as I said this is obviously controversial. 1:02:35.340 --> 1:02:39.240 I think I've identified the problem in a scientific way. 1:02:39.239 --> 1:02:44.519 That is, everyone would agree with me if they knew enough 1:02:44.523 --> 1:02:46.583 economics, but now my plan, 1:02:46.581 --> 1:02:49.861 even people who do know as much as me might disagree with me, 1:02:49.860 --> 1:02:55.000 but this is what I would--okay so here's the plan. 1:02:55.000 --> 1:02:56.680 As I said, other plans just say, "Well, 1:02:56.684 --> 1:02:57.354 things are bad. 1:02:57.349 --> 1:02:59.599 Let's just keep the same system." 1:02:59.599 --> 1:03:01.239 So there are two basic ideas. 1:03:01.239 --> 1:03:04.049 The Democratic idea is, "Let's just keep adjusting 1:03:04.054 --> 1:03:04.894 at the margin. 1:03:04.889 --> 1:03:07.669 We'll make up for it by giving people money later. 1:03:07.670 --> 1:03:09.240 We'll do all kinds of things like that. 1:03:09.239 --> 1:03:11.679 Maybe we'll raise some tax, reduce some benefits, 1:03:11.677 --> 1:03:13.047 balance the system." 1:03:13.050 --> 1:03:16.040 The Republicans want to junk the whole thing and privatize 1:03:16.043 --> 1:03:18.583 and let people, you know, force them to save, 1:03:18.577 --> 1:03:21.477 but put it in the stock market in their own account. 1:03:21.480 --> 1:03:26.260 Now, here's my plan. 1:03:26.260 --> 1:03:32.770 I don't have time to talk about Bush's plan. 1:03:32.769 --> 1:03:33.569 So here's my plan. 1:03:33.570 --> 1:03:36.630 Number one, the fact that we gave all this money away to 1:03:36.626 --> 1:03:40.386 people in the '40s, and '50s, and '60s and '70s, 1:03:40.389 --> 1:03:45.009 why should that be the responsibility of the workers 1:03:45.012 --> 1:03:45.832 today? 1:03:45.829 --> 1:03:48.429 I mean, our government decided it was a good idea. 1:03:48.429 --> 1:03:51.849 Roosevelt and Frances Perkins decided we had to rescue the old 1:03:51.849 --> 1:03:54.409 of the '40s, and our Congresses kept that up 1:03:54.405 --> 1:03:57.835 for the next 20 or 30 years even though the old weren't in such 1:03:57.838 --> 1:03:59.488 dire shape, but they kept it up. 1:03:59.489 --> 1:04:00.799 Maybe that was a good idea. 1:04:00.800 --> 1:04:03.910 It's probably a very good idea, but because we have that huge 1:04:03.909 --> 1:04:06.859 debt why should workers be the only people responsible for 1:04:06.862 --> 1:04:08.212 paying back that debt? 1:04:08.210 --> 1:04:11.990 I would start by imposing a legacy tax on everybody, 1:04:11.987 --> 1:04:15.247 not for Social Security, just for the debt we 1:04:15.248 --> 1:04:19.248 accumulated by giving it to those old generations. 1:04:19.250 --> 1:04:22.360 So I believe that would be something like 1 percent. 1:04:22.360 --> 1:04:25.450 I wrote 2 to 3 percent, but I think it's closer to 1 1:04:25.449 --> 1:04:27.569 percent, actually, on all income. 1:04:27.570 --> 1:04:31.090 If I did it on all income it would be like 1 percent and that 1:04:31.088 --> 1:04:34.138 fund would pay off for the Social Security legacy. 1:04:34.139 --> 1:04:39.349 So then if we were starting the system afresh how should we do 1:04:39.351 --> 1:04:39.781 it? 1:04:39.780 --> 1:04:42.770 And some countries like Chile decided they're going to start 1:04:42.773 --> 1:04:43.233 afresh. 1:04:43.230 --> 1:04:46.420 So how should we start afresh having gotten rid of this old 1:04:46.422 --> 1:04:48.572 debt that was hanging over our heads? 1:04:48.570 --> 1:04:56.170 Well, what would I do? 1:04:56.170 --> 1:04:59.220 I would have what I call Progressive Personal Accounts. 1:04:59.219 --> 1:05:02.939 So I like all the Republican ideas of knowing what you've 1:05:02.938 --> 1:05:06.258 got, making it yours, and making it transparent. 1:05:06.260 --> 1:05:09.710 I think that's all an extremely good idea, but why should it be 1:05:09.706 --> 1:05:12.706 that that comes from putting your money into stocks? 1:05:12.710 --> 1:05:14.360 I mean, stocks, this is an old fashioned 1:05:14.362 --> 1:05:15.932 security and it's incredibly risky. 1:05:15.929 --> 1:05:18.019 From one year to the next it totally changes. 1:05:18.018 --> 1:05:23.318 I like the idea of indexing something to wages. 1:05:23.320 --> 1:05:26.670 So I want to create a new security that I called Personal 1:05:26.672 --> 1:05:28.772 Annuitized Average Wage Security. 1:05:28.768 --> 1:05:31.668 So what this does, this is a security that just 1:05:31.672 --> 1:05:35.522 pays proportional to the wage in the whole country at the year 1:05:35.523 --> 1:05:36.473 you retire. 1:05:36.469 --> 1:05:40.099 So whenever you earn money on Social Security--I'm running out 1:05:40.097 --> 1:05:43.427 of time so I'm going to skip over this pretty quickly. 1:05:43.429 --> 1:05:46.139 So if you earn 1 dollar and you pay, 1:05:46.139 --> 1:05:48.919 let's say, 12 percent in Social Securities taxes, 1:05:48.920 --> 1:05:54.420 that income, I'm going to say that's your 1:05:54.416 --> 1:05:57.216 income, it's your 12 percent. 1:05:57.219 --> 1:06:00.899 You're going to be forced to save it, and what you're forced 1:06:00.898 --> 1:06:03.078 to do is to buy these securities. 1:06:03.079 --> 1:06:06.499 So it's a new kind of security that pays proportional to the 1:06:06.503 --> 1:06:06.913 wage. 1:06:06.909 --> 1:06:10.219 So it might pay 1 percent of the average wage. 1:06:10.219 --> 1:06:12.689 So it would pay 12 cents here, 3 cents here, 1:06:12.686 --> 1:06:14.576 and 3 quarters of a cent there. 1:06:14.579 --> 1:06:17.999 That's the wage in the economy and it would pay 1 percent of 1:06:18.003 --> 1:06:18.413 that. 1:06:18.409 --> 1:06:21.699 And how much of it would you get to buy, as much as you could 1:06:21.702 --> 1:06:24.232 afford to buy with your security, with your tax 1:06:24.226 --> 1:06:25.156 contribution. 1:06:25.159 --> 1:06:29.489 Now, that almost replicates the current system. 1:06:29.489 --> 1:06:32.919 The only difference is that it doesn't replicate the current 1:06:32.922 --> 1:06:35.892 system, there's nothing progressive about it yet. 1:06:35.889 --> 1:06:38.569 So what I would do is I would make it a progressive tax. 1:06:38.570 --> 1:06:42.230 If you're making a hugely high income I wouldn't give you the 1:06:42.230 --> 1:06:43.390 whole 12 percent. 1:06:43.389 --> 1:06:44.459 I would take part of it. 1:06:44.460 --> 1:06:47.340 And if you're making a really low income I would have the 1:06:47.335 --> 1:06:49.335 government subsidize it a little bit. 1:06:49.340 --> 1:06:51.910 So instead of getting 12 percent of your low income you'd 1:06:51.907 --> 1:06:53.557 get a little more than 12 percent. 1:06:53.559 --> 1:06:57.189 If you had a high income your 12 percent tax the government 1:06:57.192 --> 1:07:00.952 would take 1 of those 12 away from you and you'd only have 11 1:07:00.949 --> 1:07:04.519 percent that you got to put in your personal account. 1:07:04.518 --> 1:07:06.628 Now, but it has a tremendous advantage, 1:07:06.630 --> 1:07:09.370 this system, which is that if you can price 1:07:09.371 --> 1:07:11.741 the PAAWS, if you know what the market 1:07:11.744 --> 1:07:14.744 price of PAAWS is then you're balancing the system, 1:07:14.739 --> 1:07:17.499 because every time you hand somebody money you don't make 1:07:17.503 --> 1:07:20.573 some crazy promise that when you get to be old I'm going to pay 1:07:20.565 --> 1:07:23.375 you such and such dollars like the current system is. 1:07:23.380 --> 1:07:26.050 You're letting the guy, or the woman, 1:07:26.047 --> 1:07:29.797 let's say, who's working; she is buying her own Social 1:07:29.795 --> 1:07:30.975 Security benefits. 1:07:30.980 --> 1:07:35.390 So the benefits have an equal value to what she's paying for. 1:07:35.389 --> 1:07:38.879 So you've balanced the system. 1:07:38.880 --> 1:07:42.330 The legacy tax you got rid of by having the tax on everybody 1:07:42.331 --> 1:07:45.261 of 1 or 2 percent, and the balancing the system 1:07:45.262 --> 1:07:48.792 going forward is occurring because you're forcing people to 1:07:48.789 --> 1:07:51.099 buy their Social Security benefits. 1:07:51.099 --> 1:07:53.209 So anyway that's my, in a nutshell, 1:07:53.206 --> 1:07:53.946 my system. 1:07:53.949 --> 1:07:56.849 And the last thing is how are you going to get PAAWS priced by 1:07:56.851 --> 1:07:57.471 the market? 1:07:57.469 --> 1:07:59.959 Well, I'm going to get the market to trade them, 1:07:59.956 --> 1:08:02.966 and I think that would be a tremendous boon to the economy 1:08:02.974 --> 1:08:04.884 if we had these securities paid. 1:08:04.880 --> 1:08:06.930 Why is that? 1:08:06.929 --> 1:08:08.569 So how would I do that? 1:08:08.570 --> 1:08:12.130 I'd force everybody to invest only in PAAWS, 1:08:12.130 --> 1:08:14.360 which I claim are like stocks in the long run, 1:08:14.360 --> 1:08:15.890 but in the short run they're less risky, 1:08:15.889 --> 1:08:17.569 so it's a better investment vehicle, 1:08:17.569 --> 1:08:21.069 but they'd have to sell exactly 10 percent of their PAAWS into 1:08:21.074 --> 1:08:22.924 the market, and with that 10 percent of 1:08:22.922 --> 1:08:25.362 money they could hold stocks or whatever else they wanted to, 1:08:25.359 --> 1:08:29.069 and those 10 percent would all be pooled together and traded in 1:08:29.070 --> 1:08:29.850 the market. 1:08:29.850 --> 1:08:33.380 And the market then would have an idea of--a new instrument to 1:08:33.381 --> 1:08:36.451 price what they think future wages are going to be. 1:08:36.448 --> 1:08:39.278 So anybody giving a pension plan that's indexed to future 1:08:39.283 --> 1:08:42.423 wages would know what the market price of those things are, 1:08:42.420 --> 1:08:44.470 so it would dramatically help pension plans as well. 1:08:44.470 --> 1:08:49.240 Anyway, that's my idea for Social Security. 1:08:49.238 --> 1:08:54.768 So I have four minutes left and I want to end with one last 1:08:54.768 --> 1:08:59.438 thought, one last idea, which is Black-Scholes. 1:08:59.439 --> 1:09:02.989 Now, we've already done Black-Scholes in a few problem 1:09:02.989 --> 1:09:03.459 sets. 1:09:03.460 --> 1:09:06.890 So what is the idea of Black-Scholes? 1:09:06.890 --> 1:09:09.940 It's just like the idea of the example we gave. 1:09:09.939 --> 1:09:13.599 By the way, if you do come next week and you want to question me 1:09:13.604 --> 1:09:17.154 about my Social Security plan and criticize it I'd be thrilled 1:09:17.153 --> 1:09:20.353 to be criticized because you can't learn anything unless 1:09:20.351 --> 1:09:23.611 you're criticized and I think I can defend it too. 1:09:23.609 --> 1:09:26.679 But anyhow, this is an idea which obviously hasn't caught on 1:09:26.684 --> 1:09:29.034 yet because Social Security reform stopped. 1:09:29.029 --> 1:09:30.759 We've got worse problems to worry about, 1:09:30.760 --> 1:09:33.660 but if we get through this crisis the very next thing on 1:09:33.655 --> 1:09:36.705 Obama's agenda is going to be reforming Social Security. 1:09:36.710 --> 1:09:39.730 So I'm ready. 1:09:39.729 --> 1:09:43.169 So let me just end with Black-Scholes. 1:09:43.170 --> 1:09:48.420 So in 1972 Black and Scholes wrote a famous paper. 1:09:48.420 --> 1:09:49.720 And what did they do? 1:09:49.720 --> 1:09:52.940 They started off by saying, this model we had, 1:09:52.939 --> 1:09:56.909 you see, of the stock market which follows a geometric random 1:09:56.909 --> 1:09:58.609 walk, it can go up by a certain 1:09:58.609 --> 1:10:00.669 percentage or down by a certain percentage. 1:10:00.670 --> 1:10:02.480 We've used that with interest rates too. 1:10:02.479 --> 1:10:05.079 They can go up or down by a certain percentage. 1:10:05.078 --> 1:10:08.108 Here the stocks can go up or down by a certain percentage. 1:10:08.109 --> 1:10:11.739 We saw that you could solve models like that very easily. 1:10:11.738 --> 1:10:14.588 So Black and Scholes, Fischer Black who is a great 1:10:14.591 --> 1:10:17.621 economist, and Myron Scholes who won the Nobel Prize, 1:10:17.618 --> 1:10:20.468 but was not as mathematical as Fischer Black. 1:10:20.470 --> 1:10:23.100 Anyway, he started the hedge fund Long Term Capital. 1:10:23.100 --> 1:10:25.540 Myron Scholes was one of the people. 1:10:25.538 --> 1:10:30.508 They looked in 1972 at the returns each day on the S&P 1:10:30.506 --> 1:10:34.076 500, and they binned them up like this. 1:10:34.078 --> 1:10:37.898 So here are the number of times the return was between .47 1:10:37.903 --> 1:10:40.053 percent and some other number. 1:10:40.050 --> 1:10:43.320 And then they compared that to a normally distributed random 1:10:43.319 --> 1:10:46.699 variable, and look how close to normally distributed it is. 1:10:46.699 --> 1:10:47.689 It's practically like that. 1:10:47.689 --> 1:10:51.219 So this thing over here is exactly normally distributed, 1:10:51.220 --> 1:10:55.190 and this is the frequency graph of what actually happened that 1:10:55.189 --> 1:10:57.119 year, incredibly close to normally 1:10:57.122 --> 1:10:57.782 distributed. 1:10:57.779 --> 1:11:00.389 If you take the cumulative occurrence of each thing and 1:11:00.386 --> 1:11:03.426 compare it to the normal it's incredibly close to the normal. 1:11:03.430 --> 1:11:05.980 So they said, "Gosh, isn't it great, 1:11:05.978 --> 1:11:09.208 this model of things going up or down by a certain percentage 1:11:09.211 --> 1:11:11.001 every year, maybe with a drift, 1:11:11.002 --> 1:11:14.112 that's exactly the model the stock market seems to follow, 1:11:14.109 --> 1:11:17.439 and maybe interest rates follow that sort of model too," 1:11:17.442 --> 1:11:20.332 and that's why we've worked with all those models. 1:11:20.328 --> 1:11:24.858 Well, it turns out if you make those assumptions and then you 1:11:24.863 --> 1:11:29.103 try to solve for option prices you can do it very quickly 1:11:29.095 --> 1:11:32.485 through some formula, which I'm not going to have 1:11:32.488 --> 1:11:33.388 time to present. 1:11:33.390 --> 1:11:36.070 It'll only take one minute, but I'm going to skip that. 1:11:36.069 --> 1:11:37.319 So what happened then? 1:11:37.319 --> 1:11:41.379 So this was the second high point of, you know, 1:11:41.380 --> 1:11:46.500 there's the CAPM model and then the Black-Scholes model. 1:11:46.500 --> 1:11:49.350 You've done problems with Black-Scholes now in the problem 1:11:49.350 --> 1:11:51.700 set to figure out the value of a call option. 1:11:51.698 --> 1:11:54.478 So I'm just pointing out that you could put it in a spread 1:11:54.484 --> 1:11:56.884 sheet like I've done, which will be on the web. 1:11:56.880 --> 1:12:01.100 And you can do daily returns, and fix the standard deviation 1:12:01.100 --> 1:12:03.290 and stuff, and do backward induction 1:12:03.289 --> 1:12:05.619 incredibly quickly, and figure out the value of the 1:12:05.617 --> 1:12:07.817 call option, even get a closed form formula 1:12:07.819 --> 1:12:10.229 for it, and then explain why call 1:12:10.234 --> 1:12:13.474 option prices have the form that they do. 1:12:13.470 --> 1:12:15.860 So it was a great triumph and it relied on things being 1:12:15.860 --> 1:12:16.880 normally distributed. 1:12:16.880 --> 1:12:18.710 I'm down to 30 seconds. 1:12:18.710 --> 1:12:21.330 So what happened? 1:12:21.328 --> 1:12:25.708 If you do the same thing recently--so you do exactly the 1:12:25.713 --> 1:12:30.103 same thing and bin everything up like Fischer Black did, 1:12:30.097 --> 1:12:32.407 not in 1972--shit, sorry. 1:12:32.408 --> 1:12:35.898 Not in 1972 but the last five years, say, they only did one 1:12:35.902 --> 1:12:37.892 year, but you do the last five. 1:12:37.890 --> 1:12:40.750 Actually I did this a couple years ago, so from seven years 1:12:40.753 --> 1:12:41.893 ago to two years ago. 1:12:41.890 --> 1:12:44.860 If the pink thing is normally distributed and we do the same 1:12:44.863 --> 1:12:46.783 binning that Black and Scholes did, 1:12:46.779 --> 1:12:50.069 look everyday at what the return is and stick it in a bin 1:12:50.072 --> 1:12:53.352 and just do the frequency thing, what do you see? 1:12:53.350 --> 1:12:57.380 You see that there are a lot more times where in reality the 1:12:57.378 --> 1:13:00.768 move was very small, but there are a lot more times 1:13:00.766 --> 1:13:03.186 in reality where the move was very big. 1:13:03.189 --> 1:13:06.919 So this is precisely what you call a fat tail, 1:13:06.920 --> 1:13:10.160 that you get smaller moves than the normally distributed ones 1:13:10.162 --> 1:13:13.352 but also bigger moves than the normally distributed ones. 1:13:13.350 --> 1:13:14.810 So you can have some big negative moves. 1:13:14.810 --> 1:13:17.940 And so we know we've had some huge negative shocks. 1:13:17.939 --> 1:13:22.699 So I'm ending now with this thought that finance produced 1:13:22.703 --> 1:13:26.893 remarkable theories, remarkably precise predictions, 1:13:26.894 --> 1:13:31.074 and for decades at a time it seemed those were borne out in 1:13:31.074 --> 1:13:31.944 practice. 1:13:31.939 --> 1:13:35.509 But then looking back 50 years later or 30 years later on these 1:13:35.505 --> 1:13:38.835 discoveries we see that they don't do quite as well as they 1:13:38.841 --> 1:13:40.971 seem to be doing at first glance. 1:13:40.970 --> 1:13:44.030 So something's missing in the theory, and I think the subject 1:13:44.032 --> 1:13:46.892 is so exciting because it's so connected to the world. 1:13:46.890 --> 1:13:50.850 Everybody talks about finance nowadays. 1:13:50.850 --> 1:13:55.360 Anyone in the world is spending half their time thinking about 1:13:55.359 --> 1:13:59.799 finance and the theory is still up in the air because the old 1:13:59.795 --> 1:14:02.895 classics of the theory no longer hold. 1:14:02.899 --> 1:14:05.599 And so it's an exciting time to be developing a new theory and 1:14:05.595 --> 1:14:07.535 maybe you'll think about it in the future. 1:14:07.538 --> 1:14:09.048 So I'll see you, some of you, 1:14:09.051 --> 1:14:09.701 next week. 1:14:09.699 --> 1:14:14.999