WEBVTT 00:02.480 --> 00:07.400 Prof: So we're spending a couple classes these days 00:07.402 --> 00:11.982 learning basic facts and vocabulary about finance, 00:11.980 --> 00:16.140 and along the way we're trying to apply the simple lessons that 00:16.143 --> 00:20.043 Irving Fisher taught about turning a financial problem into 00:20.039 --> 00:24.069 a general equilibrium problem and making use in particular of 00:24.069 --> 00:25.479 the budget set. 00:25.480 --> 00:29.140 That very simple budget set we wrote down at the very beginning 00:29.139 --> 00:32.559 turns out to be quite useful and people often can get quite 00:32.561 --> 00:33.331 confused. 00:33.330 --> 00:36.350 So the last issue we ended with, I'm going to take up 00:36.346 --> 00:36.806 again. 00:36.810 --> 00:41.900 Suppose that you've got a very long-lived institution like 00:41.895 --> 00:42.515 Yale. 00:42.520 --> 00:45.370 How should Yale think of how much to spend every year? 00:45.370 --> 00:47.130 What is Yale's budget set? 00:47.130 --> 00:51.570 Almost every big institution like Yale creates a fiction of 00:51.566 --> 00:56.226 an annual budget and they talk about the deficit and having to 00:56.233 --> 01:00.753 bring the deficit under control and making cuts to close the 01:00.746 --> 01:04.826 deficit gap, but really there is no such 01:04.831 --> 01:07.951 thing as a one-year budget set. 01:07.950 --> 01:08.890 I mean, why one year? 01:08.890 --> 01:10.250 Why not one month? 01:10.250 --> 01:11.290 Why not one day? 01:11.290 --> 01:14.310 Nobody expects Yale to balance its budget every day. 01:14.310 --> 01:15.970 Some expenditure comes in one day. 01:15.968 --> 01:18.288 They have to hire an electrician to fix something 01:18.290 --> 01:18.920 unexpected. 01:18.920 --> 01:23.510 They're going to spend more money than they take in student 01:23.507 --> 01:25.007 tuition that day. 01:25.010 --> 01:27.840 So the fact that they're supposed to budget the balance 01:27.837 --> 01:29.457 every year is just a fiction. 01:29.459 --> 01:32.319 Irving Fisher taught us that Yale really has-- 01:32.319 --> 01:35.429 if you can borrow and lend and you don't have to worry about 01:35.434 --> 01:37.814 risk there's one infinite-lived budget set. 01:37.810 --> 01:40.430 It's an infinite horizon budget set where you just take the 01:40.434 --> 01:42.294 present value of all the expenditures, 01:42.290 --> 01:45.810 that's the left hand side, and the present value of all 01:45.811 --> 01:48.291 the revenue, that's the right hand side, 01:48.293 --> 01:51.413 and make sure that the left hand side is smaller than the 01:51.411 --> 01:54.531 right hand side over the whole course of Yale's life. 01:54.530 --> 01:59.710 So that simple principle has a tremendous implication which was 01:59.709 --> 02:04.389 overlooked, to the chagrin of the last Yale president. 02:04.390 --> 02:06.740 So as I said, the issue was in 1997, 02:06.739 --> 02:09.139 I believe, it could have been '96 something like that, 02:09.139 --> 02:12.739 1997, Benno Schmidt, who was then the Yale 02:12.738 --> 02:15.478 president, released a white paper, 02:15.483 --> 02:18.633 he called it, documenting the fact that Yale 02:18.625 --> 02:21.695 had deferred maintenance in the buildings, 02:21.699 --> 02:24.309 he called it, and a study that he 02:24.312 --> 02:26.562 commissioned, a very good study that he 02:26.562 --> 02:29.332 commissioned, argued that the deferred 02:29.327 --> 02:32.347 maintenance-- Yale could be brought up to 02:32.349 --> 02:36.349 snuff and then go on afterwards as a normal running institution 02:36.348 --> 02:40.408 provided it spent 100 million dollars a year for ten years, 02:40.410 --> 02:42.540 and that included fixing every college-- 02:42.538 --> 02:45.418 they're going to do more than one a year over a 10 year 02:45.419 --> 02:45.899 period. 02:45.900 --> 02:49.160 So Yale's total budget, as I told you, 02:49.160 --> 02:51.260 was about 1 billion dollars at the time, 02:51.258 --> 02:55.038 and then here all of a sudden was this 100 million dollar a 02:55.043 --> 02:56.873 year expense for 10 years. 02:56.870 --> 02:58.720 That's 10 percent of the Yale budget. 02:58.720 --> 03:01.560 And a lot of the costs you can't change. 03:01.560 --> 03:02.500 You have to have the lights on. 03:02.500 --> 03:03.610 You have to heat the buildings. 03:03.610 --> 03:05.870 You can't really reduce those costs. 03:05.870 --> 03:09.260 So Benno Schmidt came to the conclusion that he'd have to 03:09.258 --> 03:12.708 reduce the costs he could change by 15 percent in order to 03:12.706 --> 03:15.856 balance the budget, to cut about 100 million 03:15.864 --> 03:18.284 dollars a year out of the budget. 03:18.280 --> 03:21.990 So he announced one day that he was going to fire 15 percent of 03:21.992 --> 03:23.612 the faculty by attrition. 03:23.610 --> 03:26.070 If they were junior faculty he wouldn't promote them, 03:26.068 --> 03:28.668 and if they were senior faculty, wait until they retired 03:28.668 --> 03:29.848 and not replace them. 03:29.848 --> 03:32.838 So this, needless to say, caused a tremendous commotion 03:32.837 --> 03:35.437 among the faculty, and as I told you a committee 03:35.438 --> 03:38.038 was formed and I had to present the report. 03:38.038 --> 03:41.568 So actually the report went pretty carefully through all the 03:41.568 --> 03:43.958 calculations made in the white paper, 03:43.960 --> 03:48.550 but the heart of the report was simply to apply the lesson of 03:48.545 --> 03:49.765 Irving Fisher. 03:49.770 --> 03:51.420 So what is the lesson of Irving Fisher? 03:51.419 --> 03:54.779 Let's suppose that there's no inflation so that when they say 03:54.776 --> 03:58.246 100 million dollars a year they mean 100 million real dollars a 03:58.246 --> 03:58.746 year. 03:58.750 --> 04:02.180 So Irving Fisher would say Yale's going to live forever. 04:02.180 --> 04:06.100 Let's suppose that Yale wants the same quality of education 04:06.102 --> 04:09.912 every year forever, so it should have the same real 04:09.913 --> 04:13.743 spending every year forever after it compensates for 04:13.735 --> 04:14.705 inflation. 04:14.710 --> 04:16.530 So at the moment we're assuming there's no inflation. 04:16.529 --> 04:17.869 So what does that mean? 04:17.870 --> 04:21.380 That means that you just look at the right hand side and you 04:21.382 --> 04:23.112 say, what's Yale's revenue? 04:23.110 --> 04:26.580 Well, whatever it was before we were told by this report of the 04:26.577 --> 04:29.767 president that as long as you did the deferred maintenance 04:29.766 --> 04:31.666 Yale would be back in balance. 04:31.670 --> 04:34.880 So what's the loss of revenue on the right hand side? 04:34.879 --> 04:38.379 It's 10 years of 100 million dollars a year as you can see. 04:38.379 --> 04:40.079 Now, you need an interest rate. 04:40.079 --> 04:41.929 What should the interest rate be? 04:41.930 --> 04:45.120 Well, should it be the nominal interest rate or the real 04:45.120 --> 04:46.050 interest rate? 04:46.050 --> 04:49.060 Well, we're supposing now there's no inflation so it 04:49.060 --> 04:52.840 should be the real interest rate because all the hundreds have no 04:52.839 --> 04:54.139 inflation in them. 04:54.139 --> 04:56.519 So what real interest rate shall we use? 04:56.519 --> 05:02.179 Well, the white paper used 5 percent because they thought 05:02.175 --> 05:07.725 that was the number that Yale could earn after inflation 05:07.728 --> 05:10.858 pretty reliably every year. 05:10.860 --> 05:14.720 They think that's the real rate of return Yale gets, 05:14.721 --> 05:17.601 and so they discounted it 5 percent. 05:17.600 --> 05:20.710 Now the real rate of interest typically in the economy is 3 05:20.714 --> 05:24.264 percent, but let's suppose that we calculated this at 5 percent. 05:24.259 --> 05:29.819 The present value of 100 for 10 years is 772. 05:29.819 --> 05:31.539 Now, how could you do that in your head? 05:31.540 --> 05:46.020 Well, we know that 5 percent is going to double every 14 years, 05:46.023 --> 05:51.633 5 into 72 is about 14. 05:51.629 --> 05:58.179 If it doubles every 14 years 10 years is going to be less than 05:58.177 --> 06:01.287 half the value of the bond. 06:01.290 --> 06:04.970 So if you got 100 forever at 5 percent interest that would be 2 06:04.966 --> 06:07.156 billion, and we know for only 10 years 06:07.160 --> 06:10.570 it's less than half the value, so considerably less than half 06:10.567 --> 06:12.307 the value, so it's not one billion it's 06:12.307 --> 06:13.287 something less than that. 06:13.290 --> 06:14.560 It's 772. 06:14.560 --> 06:17.760 So I just did that in Excel and I calculated 772, 06:17.759 --> 06:21.419 but in your head you know that if it had gone on for 14 years 06:21.422 --> 06:24.242 then the present value, our formula, 06:24.240 --> 06:29.890 our famous formula is that you would take the coupon 100 06:29.887 --> 06:36.247 divided by the interest rate .05 times (1 - 1 over (1 R) to the 06:36.250 --> 06:37.380 10th). 06:37.379 --> 06:40.859 And so we know that if this were 14 instead of 10 you'd get 06:40.860 --> 06:41.700 a half here. 06:41.699 --> 06:44.579 So this is 20 times 100 which is 2 billion times 1 half would 06:44.581 --> 06:46.601 be 1 billion, but since it's only 10 years 06:46.601 --> 06:48.571 and not 14 years it's less than a billion, 06:48.569 --> 06:50.129 so 772. 06:50.129 --> 06:54.169 So in your head you could have probably figured that out 06:54.165 --> 06:55.335 approximately. 06:55.339 --> 06:57.969 So you could be sitting there in the audience hearing Benno 06:57.966 --> 07:00.676 Schmidt talk and be computing in your head that we're talking 07:00.684 --> 07:04.304 about something under 1 billion, like 3 quarters of 1 billion. 07:04.300 --> 07:07.880 So now, how much does that mean reduction in every year? 07:07.879 --> 07:12.389 Well, if Yale's going to spend the same amount every year that 07:12.391 --> 07:17.051 means it should be spending 5 percent of 772 less every year. 07:17.050 --> 07:20.740 That's 38.6 million dollars less every year. 07:20.740 --> 07:24.440 So that's a drastically smaller number than 100 million dollars 07:24.442 --> 07:24.982 a year. 07:24.980 --> 07:27.810 It's crazy just to think that because you've got these 07:27.814 --> 07:31.294 expenditures for 10 years and then no expenditures after that, 07:31.290 --> 07:34.830 that you should cut the budget by a 100 million and then let it 07:34.834 --> 07:36.154 go up after 10 years. 07:36.149 --> 07:41.479 So you'd only need to cut it by 38 million. 07:41.480 --> 07:43.330 Now, by the way, 5 percent is a pretty arbitrary 07:43.326 --> 07:43.676 number. 07:43.680 --> 07:45.830 Suppose you put 3 percent here? 07:45.829 --> 07:50.489 Well, 3 percent would give you a much higher present value, 07:50.490 --> 07:53.610 but then when you multiply it by 3 percent at the end for the 07:53.612 --> 07:56.632 annual reduction it will give you a much smaller number. 07:56.629 --> 08:02.149 Anyway, this number, which I computed in Excel, 08:02.149 --> 08:04.029 but again you can do it sort of in your head, 08:04.028 --> 08:09.048 is 853 million, but you multiply that by 3 08:09.045 --> 08:13.935 percent and you get 26 million a year. 08:13.939 --> 08:16.989 So now the reduction is starting to sound like it's not 08:16.992 --> 08:18.522 such a frightening thing. 08:18.519 --> 08:23.179 So let's stick with the 5 percent which is what the white 08:23.180 --> 08:25.220 paper, take all the assumptions of the 08:25.216 --> 08:26.706 white paper and take it literally, 08:26.709 --> 08:29.949 and then notice that they never said anything about inflation. 08:29.949 --> 08:34.039 So actually, this calculation of present 08:34.037 --> 08:40.217 value loss--there's inflation, and say the inflation at that 08:40.220 --> 08:43.260 time is around 4 percent. 08:43.259 --> 08:46.019 In fact all the Yale contracts that are still in place assume a 08:46.023 --> 08:48.923 4 percent inflation even though inflation's less than that now. 08:48.918 --> 08:52.708 But anyway, so that 100 million a year of dollars is actually 08:52.705 --> 08:56.425 less in present value terms because what should you discount 08:56.428 --> 08:56.868 by? 08:56.870 --> 08:59.220 If you look at the present value of 100 million dollars 08:59.220 --> 09:01.880 over 10 years and you take into account its dollars you should 09:01.875 --> 09:04.005 be discounting by the real interest rate times the 09:04.009 --> 09:06.489 inflation, so by 9 percent, 09:06.486 --> 09:09.416 a tiny bit over 9 percent. 09:09.418 --> 09:17.308 So if you discount that by 9 percent you get 641 million as 09:17.309 --> 09:21.799 the present value loss to Yale. 09:21.798 --> 09:27.068 Now, given that there's inflation how much should you be 09:27.071 --> 09:29.181 spending every year? 09:29.178 --> 09:32.228 You should be spending in real dollars, reducing your 09:32.230 --> 09:34.520 expenditure how much in real dollars? 09:34.519 --> 09:39.529 Well, by 5 percent of the 641 million. 09:39.529 --> 09:43.499 So if you have 641, that's today's present value. 09:43.500 --> 09:46.010 There hasn't been any inflation yet. 09:46.009 --> 09:48.799 So that's the real loss in dollars. 09:48.798 --> 09:53.278 So if you ask, what's the real expenditure 09:53.283 --> 09:58.313 reduction every year, it's 5 percent of 641 and 09:58.313 --> 10:00.723 that's 32 million. 10:00.720 --> 10:06.910 So 32 million is a far smaller number than 100 million and 10:06.914 --> 10:11.594 requires a far smaller drop in expenses, 10:11.590 --> 10:15.100 so our committee recommended that we cut the faculty by 6 10:15.096 --> 10:17.346 percent instead of by 15 percent, 10:17.350 --> 10:20.360 and 6 percent--there are a lot of people leaving every year. 10:20.360 --> 10:22.340 You can do 6 percent pretty quickly. 10:22.340 --> 10:25.480 So the upshot of this is that it is a simple application of 10:25.476 --> 10:28.016 present value, a very elementary calculation. 10:28.019 --> 10:31.269 It came as somewhat of a revelation to our 10:31.267 --> 10:34.747 administrators, I'm afraid, and the day after 10:34.751 --> 10:39.031 the report the provost of the university resigned. 10:39.029 --> 10:42.569 Two weeks later the dean of the university resigned and two 10:42.565 --> 10:45.975 months later the president of the university resigned. 10:45.980 --> 10:49.270 And Rick Levin, the current president, 10:49.269 --> 10:53.269 took over and he cut the faculty by 6 percent, 10:53.270 --> 10:55.850 but by no more than that. 10:55.850 --> 10:58.510 And then, of course, the finances of Yale got much 10:58.506 --> 11:01.976 better and he's since added back that 6 percent plus a little bit 11:01.979 --> 11:03.009 more than that. 11:03.009 --> 11:05.519 So just to tell you, though, something good about 11:05.522 --> 11:08.302 the Yale administration, the provost who resigned that 11:08.296 --> 11:10.596 next day happens to be a friend of mine. 11:10.600 --> 11:15.630 I've had dinner with him every month for the last 12 years 11:15.626 --> 11:20.476 since this happened and he's never once criticized me or 11:20.477 --> 11:25.857 shown the slightest discomfort about the report that basically 11:25.857 --> 11:29.207 ended his administrative career. 11:29.210 --> 11:33.090 He cares so much about Yale and was so determined to do the 11:33.091 --> 11:34.031 right thing. 11:34.029 --> 11:37.639 He just thought he made a miscalculation and stepped 11:37.643 --> 11:38.213 aside. 11:38.210 --> 11:42.930 So I believe that he wanted to do the right thing for Yale and 11:42.931 --> 11:47.091 just made the wrong calculation, not that he had some political 11:47.092 --> 11:50.002 agenda or something to cut such a huge part of the faculty. 11:50.000 --> 11:56.720 So it's the most honest and most Yale-loving administrator 11:56.721 --> 11:59.671 that you could imagine. 11:59.668 --> 12:02.488 And I didn't know what the reaction would be of someone 12:02.490 --> 12:04.320 like him after giving the report. 12:04.320 --> 12:06.530 I was quite terrified, actually, that they'd be-- 12:06.528 --> 12:08.588 they were still the president, the provost and the dean, 12:08.590 --> 12:10.590 that they would be quite angry at our committee, 12:10.590 --> 12:16.570 but they responded with tremendous integrity. 12:16.570 --> 12:17.340 Yes? 12:17.340 --> 12:20.330 Student: Why did you multiply the present value by 12:20.326 --> 12:23.416 the interest rate to find the >? 12:23.419 --> 12:24.139 Prof: You tell me. 12:24.139 --> 12:26.239 Why did I do that? 12:26.240 --> 12:29.830 So someone else tell me. 12:29.830 --> 12:30.820 So that's a good question. 12:30.820 --> 12:32.260 Why is that? 12:32.259 --> 12:32.849 Yes? 12:32.850 --> 12:35.820 Student: It's like finding the coupon of the 12:35.822 --> 12:38.502 perpetuity with a 5 percent interest rate, 12:38.500 --> 12:43.080 because it's like you're rearranging C over r equals the 12:43.075 --> 12:46.275 present value, so it'd make it present value 12:46.284 --> 12:48.394 times the interest rate equals C. 12:48.389 --> 12:48.789 Prof: Right. 12:48.788 --> 12:52.908 So the question was why, after I figured out the present 12:52.913 --> 12:56.993 value loss like 772 million, why did I multiply that by 5 12:56.993 --> 13:00.813 percent to figure out how much Yale should reduce its spending 13:00.812 --> 13:01.692 every year. 13:01.690 --> 13:05.210 And the answer that was given down here is that I'm assuming 13:05.205 --> 13:07.465 that Yale is going to go on forever. 13:07.470 --> 13:10.690 So Yale can reduce its expenditures every year forever 13:10.687 --> 13:14.387 and by doing that make up for the same present value loss, 13:14.389 --> 13:18.589 so forever means perpetually, so it's a perpetuity. 13:18.590 --> 13:21.940 So how much do you have to reduce-- 13:21.940 --> 13:26.070 what is the coupon reduction, the expenditure reduction every 13:26.065 --> 13:29.975 year at 5 percent interest that just makes a present value 13:29.982 --> 13:31.842 decline of 772 million? 13:31.840 --> 13:34.190 Well, it's 5 percent of the principal. 13:34.190 --> 13:38.490 If you have 772 million in the bank and every year 5 percent of 13:38.493 --> 13:41.993 that you throw away, you've thrown away the whole 13:41.986 --> 13:44.446 value, at 5 percent interest, 13:44.452 --> 13:46.202 of the 772 million. 13:46.200 --> 13:50.540 So by reducing your expenditures by 5 percent every 13:50.543 --> 13:54.543 year you defray the 772 million dollar loss. 13:54.538 --> 13:58.098 So the critical thing, the critical mistake that the 13:58.095 --> 14:02.485 administration made is they had a short run problem with a bunch 14:02.485 --> 14:05.875 of short run costs, but Yale's going to live 14:05.884 --> 14:10.134 forever and Yale should share the cost and the loss over all 14:10.125 --> 14:12.895 future generations, not just make the current 14:12.898 --> 14:14.508 faculty, and the current students, 14:14.509 --> 14:20.809 and the current city bear all the costs of this one shot loss, 14:20.808 --> 14:23.848 one shot problem that Yale faced. 14:23.850 --> 14:27.270 So they weren't thinking in Fisher's terms of taking the 14:27.274 --> 14:30.824 present value over the whole course of the lifetime of the 14:30.822 --> 14:31.822 institution. 14:31.820 --> 14:33.890 They were thinking, well, we've got to spend 100 14:33.894 --> 14:36.504 million dollars this year we better cut costs by 100 million 14:36.500 --> 14:37.030 dollars. 14:37.029 --> 14:38.759 But that's obviously crazy. 14:38.759 --> 14:42.439 Like suppose you had to spend an extra 100,000 dollars in one 14:42.441 --> 14:42.811 day. 14:42.808 --> 14:46.898 Does that mean you should lay off your faculty for one day so 14:46.904 --> 14:49.434 you can find the money to pay that? 14:49.428 --> 14:52.628 And of course not, so you have to spread the loss 14:52.633 --> 14:55.173 over the lifetime of the university. 14:55.168 --> 14:58.188 Are there any other questions about this principle? 14:58.190 --> 14:59.050 Yes? 14:59.048 --> 15:02.418 Student: If you wanted to return to say spending 100 15:02.424 --> 15:05.804 million dollars a year again after 10 years would you spend 15:05.801 --> 15:09.471 77 million a year for those just 10 years if you wanted to incur 15:09.467 --> 15:12.317 the whole cost over a fixed period of time? 15:12.320 --> 15:15.290 Prof: If I wanted to incur the whole cost over 10 15:15.288 --> 15:15.718 years? 15:15.720 --> 15:16.180 Student: Yes. 15:16.178 --> 15:20.158 Prof: Then I would have to reduce my expenditures by 100 15:20.163 --> 15:21.773 million dollars a year. 15:21.769 --> 15:26.999 If at the end of 10 years I wanted to be back even then I 15:26.998 --> 15:29.518 would have to spend less. 15:29.519 --> 15:31.919 I would have to cut my expenditures by exactly the 15:31.921 --> 15:33.931 money I was pouring into the buildings. 15:33.928 --> 15:37.238 So if I wanted to reduce my expenditures by an equal amount 15:37.236 --> 15:40.426 every year it would have to be 100 million dollars for 10 15:40.429 --> 15:41.399 years, right? 15:41.399 --> 15:47.359 If the maintenance costs go over a 10-year period and I want 15:47.361 --> 15:51.811 the expenditures to go over a 10-year period, 15:51.808 --> 15:52.818 right? 15:52.820 --> 15:56.230 So if I want the expenditures to be reduced evenly over a 15:56.227 --> 15:59.817 10-year period I'd have to do 100 million dollars a year. 15:59.820 --> 16:02.300 If I wanted to eat away the costs all in 1 year--I guess I 16:02.302 --> 16:03.872 didn't understand you're question. 16:03.870 --> 16:07.760 You're saying if I wanted to reduce expenditures entirely in 16:07.764 --> 16:11.334 1 year and then return next year to my usual pattern of 16:11.328 --> 16:15.418 expenditure then I'd have to cut the 1 billion dollar budget by 16:15.421 --> 16:16.611 772 million. 16:16.610 --> 16:20.300 So that would involve basically firing the whole faculty and 16:20.296 --> 16:24.166 saying take a year off you're on furlough, sort of what they're 16:24.169 --> 16:25.669 doing in California. 16:25.669 --> 16:26.529 Yes? 16:26.528 --> 16:29.638 Student: Can you also spread the present value cost 16:29.639 --> 16:32.799 evenly over 10 years and not like 100 million dollars every 16:32.803 --> 16:35.183 year, but 100 million in present 16:35.182 --> 16:36.102 value terms. 16:36.100 --> 16:37.170 Prof: I could do that if I wanted. 16:37.168 --> 16:40.558 I could rearrange the 100 million any way I wanted to. 16:40.558 --> 16:43.898 So you would cut less than 100 million dollars this year out of 16:43.904 --> 16:46.984 the budget and a little bit more every year after that? 16:46.980 --> 16:50.320 Student: Assuming you wanted to get these costs over 16:50.315 --> 16:52.035 with in a 10-year timeframe. 16:52.038 --> 16:54.638 Prof: Well, one way to do the costs over 16:54.635 --> 16:57.285 with in a 10-year timeframe is reduce costs, 16:57.288 --> 17:00.568 reduce paying the faculty by 100 million dollars every year 17:00.573 --> 17:01.873 for 10 years, right? 17:01.870 --> 17:04.410 That would obviously do it, because that's the money I need 17:04.405 --> 17:04.795 to get. 17:04.798 --> 17:07.548 You could now rearrange that by reducing costs a little less at 17:07.545 --> 17:10.285 the beginning and a little more at the end of the 10 years, 17:10.288 --> 17:13.208 but I would say that doesn't sound-- 17:13.210 --> 17:14.060 why do that? 17:14.058 --> 17:17.918 That's kind of what bad politicians do. 17:17.920 --> 17:20.950 They say, "It's not our fault. 17:20.950 --> 17:24.230 We'll just make those guys in year 10 get totally 17:24.227 --> 17:27.027 crushed," and pretty soon they are in 17:27.026 --> 17:31.666 year 10 and then they've got 200 million they have to cut costs. 17:31.670 --> 17:32.680 Yes? 17:32.680 --> 17:36.020 Student: So say in 25 years Yale wants to do another 17:36.016 --> 17:39.236 round of rebuilding all of the buildings they'll still be 17:39.238 --> 17:42.688 paying for the buildings that they built 25 years prior? 17:42.690 --> 17:43.050 Prof: Right. 17:43.049 --> 17:44.539 So there's a good question. 17:44.538 --> 17:48.608 So actually some people, the administration, 17:48.608 --> 17:50.768 that was their best response, they said, 17:50.769 --> 17:53.859 "Well even though the white paper said this was a one 17:53.859 --> 17:57.049 shot thing, and after we do this 10 year 17:57.054 --> 18:01.904 plan Yale is back in good shape, and of course every year Yale 18:01.901 --> 18:04.121 has allowed maintenance expenses. 18:04.118 --> 18:05.778 That's part of the budget is maintenance. 18:05.778 --> 18:08.968 So after we get the buildings back in tip top shape we're 18:08.973 --> 18:12.173 going to keep them in tip top shape by doing these normal 18:12.169 --> 18:15.649 expenditures every year so we should never have another period 18:15.648 --> 18:19.128 where you have to do something drastic like that." 18:19.130 --> 18:22.240 That's what the white paper said, but after the report they 18:22.244 --> 18:23.914 responded just like you said. 18:23.910 --> 18:26.020 They said, "Well, we didn't really mean that. 18:26.019 --> 18:30.009 Maybe in 25 years we're going to have to do another remodeling 18:30.009 --> 18:30.989 effort." 18:30.990 --> 18:34.040 And so well, if you need to that then it 18:34.040 --> 18:37.640 wasn't just a one-time deferred maintenance. 18:37.640 --> 18:40.910 It means that you've drastically underestimated the 18:40.913 --> 18:44.913 cost of keeping up the buildings over Yale's whole future, 18:44.910 --> 18:49.520 so then you would have these reductions in expenditures for 18:49.523 --> 18:54.383 the first 10 years and then in year 35 you'd have to have more 18:54.376 --> 18:57.156 reductions, and then in year 70 you'd have 18:57.164 --> 18:58.534 more reductions like that. 18:58.529 --> 19:01.729 So you have to take the present value of all those things and 19:01.731 --> 19:04.771 then figure out how much to reduce expenditures on an even 19:04.773 --> 19:07.713 basis and so it would be much more than 32 million. 19:07.710 --> 19:11.820 It would be 60 or something million or 50 million. 19:11.818 --> 19:13.618 So you're exactly right, but that's not what they said 19:13.616 --> 19:14.326 in the white paper. 19:14.328 --> 19:20.228 So I took them literally what they meant. 19:20.230 --> 19:21.390 So what happened after that? 19:21.390 --> 19:24.640 Yale has done much more building expenditures than that, 19:24.642 --> 19:28.192 but that's because Yale's endowment went up to 23 billion. 19:28.190 --> 19:31.340 So from 3 billion which it was at the time it's now 23 billion 19:31.344 --> 19:33.984 so Yale's launched an incredible program of building 19:33.980 --> 19:34.860 construction. 19:34.858 --> 19:36.108 Basically they've done two things. 19:36.108 --> 19:40.668 They've built a huge number of construction jobs and they've 19:40.665 --> 19:43.905 hired a lot of administrators and stuff. 19:43.910 --> 19:47.990 So the faculty is still not that much bigger. 19:47.990 --> 19:49.580 It went down 6 percent. 19:49.578 --> 19:51.908 It's now back a little bigger than it was before. 19:51.910 --> 19:55.240 So the plan to expand the college and expand the faculty 19:55.244 --> 19:56.584 hasn't happened yet. 19:56.578 --> 19:59.538 So Yale faces another choice now. 19:59.538 --> 20:03.778 You know the endowment went to 23 billion and then this past 20:03.780 --> 20:06.940 year they managed to lose down to 17 billion, 20:06.943 --> 20:08.673 30 percent got lost. 20:08.670 --> 20:11.190 So we're down to 17 billion now. 20:11.190 --> 20:12.500 So again we have the same question. 20:12.500 --> 20:14.050 We just lost 6 billion dollars. 20:14.048 --> 20:20.628 How much should we reduce expenditures every year? 20:20.630 --> 20:23.800 So what's your answer to that? 20:23.798 --> 20:28.338 Student: About 30 percent? 20:28.339 --> 20:32.489 Prof: Not 30 percent. 20:32.490 --> 20:36.540 So how much would you reduce expenditures? 20:36.539 --> 20:38.009 Why wouldn't it be 30 percent? 20:38.009 --> 20:41.179 Because Yale spends a lot of money it doesn't get from the 20:41.182 --> 20:42.242 endowment, right? 20:42.240 --> 20:47.620 It gets money from tuition, for example. 20:47.619 --> 20:48.369 So what should Yale do? 20:48.368 --> 20:50.708 What do you think Yale's going to have to take out of the 20:50.707 --> 20:51.247 budget now? 20:51.250 --> 20:56.270 Student: > 20:56.271 --> 20:58.031 calculation. 20:58.029 --> 20:59.949 Prof: Yeah, and let's say it's still 5 20:59.953 --> 21:02.013 percent real interest then what would you do? 21:02.009 --> 21:07.269 Student: Present value's 6 billion dollars and we assume 21:07.266 --> 21:09.806 we're at 5 percent interest. 21:09.808 --> 21:10.438 Prof: Yeah, so what's that? 21:10.440 --> 21:12.800 Student: 6 over .05? 21:12.798 --> 21:17.328 Prof: 6 times .05, so what's that? 21:17.328 --> 21:20.088 Hard to do these things in your head, right, but what is it? 21:20.089 --> 21:21.849 Student: 300 million. 21:21.849 --> 21:25.429 Prof: 300 million, so Yale's got to somehow cut 21:25.430 --> 21:30.210 300 million out of its budget so it's not going to do it in one 21:30.214 --> 21:32.154 year, but over the course of the next 21:32.153 --> 21:34.123 few years it's going to have to cut 300 million. 21:34.118 --> 21:37.878 Now the budget is well over 2 billion so that's 15 percent of 21:37.883 --> 21:41.023 the budget, though, Yale's going to have to cut. 21:41.019 --> 21:42.139 So this is a serious thing. 21:42.140 --> 21:45.510 How do you cut 15 percent of the Yale budget? 21:45.509 --> 21:46.639 Student: Firing faculty. 21:46.640 --> 21:48.960 Prof: Firing faculty, well, I hope they don't do 21:48.959 --> 21:49.259 that. 21:49.259 --> 21:54.289 I think they learned their lesson so I doubt if they'll do 21:54.291 --> 21:54.911 that. 21:54.910 --> 21:56.270 Things are already changing. 21:56.269 --> 22:00.589 They're charging for long distance telephone calls and all 22:00.592 --> 22:02.642 kinds of stuff like that. 22:02.640 --> 22:04.940 That doesn't get you quite 300 million, but there's going to be 22:04.942 --> 22:06.022 a bunch of stuff like that. 22:06.019 --> 22:07.609 So anyway, we have another budget problem, 22:07.605 --> 22:08.105 by the way. 22:08.108 --> 22:10.478 So these kinds of budget problems are happening all over 22:10.477 --> 22:11.077 the country. 22:11.078 --> 22:15.268 I gave a talk at Albany University and they're going to 22:15.267 --> 22:19.607 abolish their graduate economics program, SUNY Albany. 22:19.608 --> 22:23.638 These are serious problems losing that much money. 22:23.640 --> 22:26.670 But in any case 6 billion translates to, 22:26.670 --> 22:30.700 right, the difference here is 6 billion and you multiply that by 22:30.702 --> 22:34.352 .05 just as we said and that equals 300 million a year. 22:34.348 --> 22:38.108 So Yale won't do it right away, but over the course of a few 22:38.111 --> 22:41.491 years Yale's going to have to reduce its budget by 300 22:41.490 --> 22:44.230 million, so they're going to obviously 22:44.234 --> 22:48.334 choose to do a lot less building and presumably some of the new 22:48.330 --> 22:51.700 people that got hired they're going to not keep. 22:51.700 --> 22:54.370 So any other questions? 22:54.369 --> 22:54.899 Yep? 22:54.900 --> 22:57.920 Student: Doesn't that presume that the endowment stays 22:57.924 --> 22:58.484 that way? 22:58.480 --> 23:00.050 Prof: Yes. 23:00.048 --> 23:03.718 Student: Could you also, once the stock market and the 23:03.718 --> 23:07.448 real estate goes back up, can you have some assumption 23:07.450 --> 23:10.120 that they don't need to cut as much? 23:10.118 --> 23:11.688 Prof: Right, very good question. 23:11.690 --> 23:15.580 So in the front he's saying this presumes that we know for 23:15.575 --> 23:18.365 sure that the endowment lost 6 billion. 23:18.369 --> 23:20.119 It'll never recover it. 23:20.118 --> 23:23.778 Maybe that's a temporary drop in the stock market and it'll go 23:23.778 --> 23:26.048 back up, and basically the principle 23:26.048 --> 23:29.378 he's applying is he's saying you can't make these drastic 23:29.384 --> 23:31.654 reductions in annual expenditures, 23:31.650 --> 23:34.210 firing people and then two years later realizing you've got 23:34.211 --> 23:36.821 a lot of money trying to hire them back because you won't be 23:36.817 --> 23:38.007 able to hire them back. 23:38.009 --> 23:41.369 So clearly Yale has to have a more complicated rule about how 23:41.374 --> 23:44.404 it gradually adjusts its spending when there's a change 23:44.402 --> 23:45.582 in the endowment. 23:45.578 --> 23:47.498 And so we're going to talk about that later because it 23:47.503 --> 23:49.613 involves uncertainty and how to think about uncertainty. 23:49.609 --> 23:52.949 But you're absolutely right. 23:52.950 --> 23:56.210 So Levin did not announce a 300 million dollar reduction 23:56.210 --> 23:58.100 immediately, but he announced a big 23:58.098 --> 24:00.618 reduction immediately, and you're going to expect next 24:00.622 --> 24:03.582 year if the stock market doesn't drastically improve for there to 24:03.579 --> 24:04.689 be another reduction. 24:04.690 --> 24:07.360 And, by the way, this number could go down as 24:07.356 --> 24:08.626 well as it goes up. 24:08.630 --> 24:11.730 So we're going to come back to Yale's investments and what 24:11.732 --> 24:12.552 they're like. 24:12.548 --> 24:15.108 A lot of Yale's investments are called private equity 24:15.105 --> 24:17.165 investments that are very hard to value. 24:17.170 --> 24:20.540 So for all we know this 17 is a lot worse than that, 24:20.535 --> 24:23.895 but we'll be finding out in the next year or two. 24:23.900 --> 24:27.400 It's not like a hedge fund where you have to value all your 24:27.401 --> 24:30.481 assets by what the market will be willing to pay. 24:30.480 --> 24:33.550 A lot of these assets there is no market so they just sort of 24:33.547 --> 24:35.027 make up what the number is. 24:35.029 --> 24:37.709 Anyway, we're going to come back and discuss this. 24:37.710 --> 24:41.990 It's a very interesting question. 24:41.990 --> 24:44.920 So one last thing about this present value calculation, 24:44.920 --> 24:49.220 one last obvious thing, it's hard to keep in your mind 24:49.221 --> 24:52.631 the difference between real and nominal. 24:52.630 --> 24:55.510 So let's just do a very simple thing. 24:55.509 --> 25:03.489 The mortgage, mortgages are traditionally 25:03.490 --> 25:08.480 nominal fixed payments. 25:08.480 --> 25:16.720 So for example, a 100,000 dollar 30 year 25:16.718 --> 25:28.968 mortgage at 2.3 percent is about 4,600 dollars per year. 25:28.970 --> 25:31.190 How did I do that so quickly in my head? 25:31.190 --> 25:35.220 Well, because I know if the interest rate is 2.3 percent and 25:35.221 --> 25:39.051 you're going to pay it forever you'd pay 2,300 a year. 25:39.048 --> 25:43.128 We know at 30 years at 2.3 percent, 2.3 percent doubles 25:43.125 --> 25:44.705 almost in 30 years. 25:44.710 --> 25:46.320 That's 69. 25:46.318 --> 25:49.018 That's getting pretty close to 72, so maybe it takes 31 years 25:49.016 --> 25:50.136 or something to double. 25:50.140 --> 25:58.420 So after 30 years the remainder is worth half the mortgage. 25:58.420 --> 26:01.310 So you've lost half of the value by only getting it for 30 26:01.313 --> 26:01.723 years. 26:01.720 --> 26:05.800 So instead of paying 2,300 you have to pay 4,600. 26:05.798 --> 26:12.588 So the coupon over .023 times (1 - 1 over 1.023 to the 26:12.586 --> 26:17.136 thirtieth), that's 1 - 1 half about, 26:17.140 --> 26:23.460 so if this coupon equals 100,000 the payment is going to 26:23.463 --> 26:25.913 be-- since this is 1 half the 26:25.906 --> 26:28.156 payment isn't going to be 2,300. 26:28.160 --> 26:30.500 It has to be twice that, 4,600. 26:30.500 --> 26:32.940 So it's 4,600 per year. 26:32.940 --> 26:35.590 So if there's no inflation that means you're making the same 26:35.590 --> 26:36.760 real payment every year. 26:36.759 --> 26:38.759 Now what happens if there's inflation? 26:38.759 --> 26:47.309 What if inflation goes up? 26:47.308 --> 26:54.798 Now what's going to happen to what you have to pay? 26:54.799 --> 27:00.129 How would you figure that out? 27:00.130 --> 27:04.580 Well, if inflation is another 2.3 percent or something, 27:04.578 --> 27:10.868 then the nominal interest rate 1 i is going to equal the real 27:10.874 --> 27:15.494 interest rate times the rate of inflation. 27:15.490 --> 27:19.790 So let's say this is 1.023 and this is also 1.023, 27:19.794 --> 27:23.574 so that's 1.046, a little bit more than 4 6, 27:23.570 --> 27:26.910 almost a little bit more than 4 6. 27:26.910 --> 27:31.700 So you know that the interest rate the mortgage companies are 27:31.703 --> 27:35.143 now going to charge is going to be 1.046. 27:35.140 --> 27:40.800 So the 4.6 is going to be the mortgage interest rate and so 27:40.799 --> 27:46.559 you can figure out by the same calculation what the coupon's 27:46.557 --> 27:48.117 going to be. 27:48.118 --> 27:52.358 So what's the coupon going to be? 27:52.358 --> 27:56.838 Well, instead of doubling every 30 years at 4.6 percent it's 27:56.835 --> 28:00.395 going to double approximately every 15 years. 28:00.400 --> 28:03.510 So this is going to be doubling twice. 28:03.509 --> 28:06.929 This is 1 quarter, so this'll be 3 quarters here. 28:06.930 --> 28:19.840 And so if you multiply everything, 2,300 a year times 4 28:19.842 --> 28:31.322 thirds--am I doing the right calculation here? 28:31.318 --> 28:39.018 I'm telling you it's so easy to compute in your head and 28:39.019 --> 28:40.699 meanwhile. 28:40.700 --> 28:44.940 Oh, I forgot to change this to 4 6, so the interest rate is 4 28:44.936 --> 28:45.216 6. 28:45.220 --> 28:54.290 So this to the other side is 4,600 times 4 thirds and that's 28:54.288 --> 28:56.438 6,000 about. 28:56.440 --> 29:02.400 So the annual payment is going to go up to 6,000 instead of 29:02.397 --> 29:03.217 4,600. 29:03.220 --> 29:04.880 It was 4,600. 29:04.880 --> 29:07.690 The interest rate went up because there was inflation, 29:07.690 --> 29:11.420 so of course they're going to ask you for more money every 29:11.415 --> 29:14.545 year, because if you pay the same 29:14.554 --> 29:19.304 amount every year and this is the real payment-- 29:19.298 --> 29:22.438 if you make the same amount and this is time in terms of 29:22.443 --> 29:25.533 inflation corrected dollars you're paying less and less 29:25.531 --> 29:26.391 every year. 29:26.390 --> 29:29.950 So clearly if you started with no inflation and a number like 29:29.953 --> 29:33.483 this, so no inflation and now you've 29:33.480 --> 29:38.360 got inflation but the same real interest rate, 29:38.358 --> 29:40.658 and the present value of your expenditures, 29:40.660 --> 29:43.420 the real present value, right--the mortgage company's 29:43.417 --> 29:45.897 going to want, the lender's going to want to 29:45.895 --> 29:49.265 get the same amount back in real terms as it got before because 29:49.265 --> 29:51.815 the inflation hasn't changed the real world. 29:51.818 --> 29:55.368 So Irving Fisher would say the inflation is just a veil. 29:55.368 --> 29:58.238 Everybody's going to want the same real interest rate and so 29:58.236 --> 30:01.196 the mortgage is going to have to return the same real thing it 30:01.201 --> 30:01.931 did before. 30:01.930 --> 30:04.510 The present value in real terms, or the real payments is 30:04.513 --> 30:05.833 still going to be 100,000. 30:05.828 --> 30:08.898 So if the real payments go down over time and have the same 30:08.903 --> 30:11.873 present value they had before it's got to be that they're 30:11.871 --> 30:15.211 higher at the beginning and in real terms lower at the end. 30:15.210 --> 30:21.560 So sure enough 6,000 is a much higher number at the beginning 30:21.555 --> 30:22.925 than 4,600. 30:22.930 --> 30:26.480 So of course when inflation went up and everybody knows it's 30:26.482 --> 30:30.042 up the mortgage companies are going to ask for higher annual 30:30.036 --> 30:33.706 payments so it'd be 6,000 a year instead of 4,600 a year. 30:33.710 --> 30:36.230 But now if you inflation correct that, 30:36.230 --> 30:38.430 the 6,000 every year is going to be less, 30:38.430 --> 30:41.610 in terms of real goods, less and less every year, 30:41.608 --> 30:44.488 but the present discounted value of this thing has to be 30:44.486 --> 30:46.156 the same as where you started. 30:46.160 --> 30:49.240 So the effect is the young borrowers are going to be 30:49.238 --> 30:52.678 spending a lot more in real goods when they're young and a 30:52.679 --> 30:54.489 lot less when they're old. 30:54.490 --> 30:58.950 So inflation has an unfortunate impact on mortgages quoted in 30:58.950 --> 31:03.560 nominal dollars that it makes the repayments happen earlier. 31:03.558 --> 31:06.398 So the young who have less money are having to pay a huge 31:06.402 --> 31:08.202 amount, and when they get old the 31:08.198 --> 31:10.768 inflation's so high that that same 6,000 dollars is 31:10.773 --> 31:11.963 practically nothing. 31:11.960 --> 31:13.800 So when they're 50 and 60 they're paying 31:13.804 --> 31:16.694 practically--they're peanuts to them, but when they were young 31:16.688 --> 31:18.058 it was really a hardship. 31:18.058 --> 31:20.758 So there's a big problem with nominal mortgages, 31:20.759 --> 31:23.919 which is that in inflationary times it kills the housing 31:23.917 --> 31:24.547 market. 31:24.548 --> 31:28.448 Fortunately we're not in inflationary times. 31:28.450 --> 31:31.160 Any questions about that? 31:31.160 --> 31:35.330 All right, so that's the basic lesson of taking the present 31:35.334 --> 31:35.914 value. 31:35.910 --> 31:39.390 And again, you've always got to sort out the nominal from the 31:39.385 --> 31:41.105 real, and look though the veil, 31:41.105 --> 31:44.265 and don't get all mixed up by the fact that there's inflation. 31:44.269 --> 31:47.619 It's the real thing that you want to concentrate on as much 31:47.618 --> 31:48.368 as you can. 31:48.368 --> 31:51.718 So that's it for the obvious lesson of present value. 31:51.720 --> 31:55.190 Now I want to introduce another word which is very famous in 31:55.191 --> 31:55.781 finance. 31:55.779 --> 31:58.429 It's called the yield or yield to maturity. 31:58.430 --> 32:02.510 And I'm going to do it, unlike the way I've presented 32:02.509 --> 32:05.879 in the notes, I'm going to do it in terms of 32:05.883 --> 32:09.103 a hedge fund, so if you can see this? 32:09.098 --> 32:14.768 So yield, the next topic, or yield to maturity is a way 32:14.769 --> 32:21.279 of trying to compute one number that summarizes how good a bond 32:21.278 --> 32:23.118 is, or how good, 32:23.119 --> 32:25.789 how well a hedge fund has done. 32:25.788 --> 32:30.428 So I think the more interesting case, and the less obvious one, 32:30.432 --> 32:32.832 is to start with a hedge fund. 32:32.828 --> 32:36.118 How do you measure how well a hedge fund's doing or how well 32:36.121 --> 32:37.461 it's done in the past? 32:37.460 --> 32:39.560 Yeah, how well it's done in the past. 32:39.558 --> 32:43.358 We're going to spend a lot of the course talking about this in 32:43.355 --> 32:45.775 various ways, but the first way to do it 32:45.780 --> 32:47.710 involves yield to maturity. 32:47.710 --> 32:51.350 So let's see why the problem is a little complicated. 32:51.348 --> 32:54.528 So I imagine that there are three investors in this hedge 32:54.531 --> 32:54.931 fund. 32:54.930 --> 32:58.600 So every year some of the investors are going to decide 32:58.603 --> 33:02.553 what to do, and they're going to decide whether to withdraw 33:02.548 --> 33:03.228 money. 33:03.230 --> 33:04.310 Here's investor one. 33:04.308 --> 33:05.758 Maybe he's going to withdraw money. 33:05.759 --> 33:07.069 The hedge fund's just beginning. 33:07.068 --> 33:09.058 He's going to put in 100 dollars. 33:09.058 --> 33:11.418 The other two guys haven't done anything. 33:11.420 --> 33:16.490 So now the hedge fund before this guy put in his money had 33:16.490 --> 33:17.380 nothing. 33:17.380 --> 33:18.390 It's just beginning. 33:18.390 --> 33:22.310 He's put in his 100 dollars, so the hedge fund's got 100 33:22.307 --> 33:23.017 dollars. 33:23.019 --> 33:24.229 So that's it. 33:24.230 --> 33:27.180 So I'm imagining these all happen, they usually happen 33:27.180 --> 33:29.240 quarterly or annually or something. 33:29.240 --> 33:30.550 They don't happen every day. 33:30.548 --> 33:33.128 There's a fixed moment at which everyone deposits their money. 33:33.130 --> 33:35.160 So let's say they happen annually. 33:35.160 --> 33:38.080 The guy puts in 100 dollars at the beginning of the year. 33:38.078 --> 33:39.968 For the rest of the year nobody can do anything. 33:39.970 --> 33:41.090 They can't take money out. 33:41.089 --> 33:42.629 They can't put money in. 33:42.630 --> 33:46.870 So the hedge fund, let's say, manages to put the 33:46.874 --> 33:51.484 100 dollars to work and finds a 7 percent return. 33:51.480 --> 33:56.680 So it's now got, the hedge fund all together has 33:56.678 --> 33:58.668 got 107 dollars. 33:58.670 --> 34:03.560 So let's just go to the hedge fund all together. 34:03.558 --> 34:08.098 The hedge fund had 100 after these guys, because only one guy 34:08.096 --> 34:12.326 put in money and now the hedge fund's got 107 dollars. 34:12.329 --> 34:14.889 Well, that 107 dollars is all the first guy's money, 34:14.889 --> 34:16.999 because nobody else has put anything in. 34:17.000 --> 34:18.210 He still owns it. 34:18.210 --> 34:21.670 So, so far the hedge fund got a 7 percent return. 34:21.670 --> 34:25.220 Well, now the next year, we're now at the beginning of 34:25.219 --> 34:28.119 year 2, our first investor thinks to 34:28.121 --> 34:30.011 himself, "Well, they did fine, 34:30.010 --> 34:33.930 7 percent, not great, but I'm okay. 34:33.929 --> 34:36.699 I'm not going to do anything, won't take any money out or put 34:36.695 --> 34:37.105 any in. 34:37.110 --> 34:42.520 A rich second investor puts in 1,000 and another guy puts in 34:42.518 --> 34:43.068 200. 34:43.070 --> 34:48.310 So now what's happened to the NAV of the fund? 34:48.309 --> 34:52.859 Well, the first guy, at the moment they put in the 34:52.864 --> 34:57.794 money, the first guy still owns 107 of the dollars. 34:57.789 --> 35:03.249 The second guy's now got 1,000 in the fund and the third guy's 35:03.251 --> 35:08.261 got 200 in the fund and the hedge fund now has 1,200 plus 35:08.264 --> 35:09.344 the 107. 35:09.340 --> 35:10.380 That's 1,307. 35:10.380 --> 35:12.140 That's how much money is in the fund. 35:12.139 --> 35:15.459 So that's at the beginning of year 2 if you're still following 35:15.458 --> 35:15.838 this. 35:15.840 --> 35:17.570 If you're not following it interrupt me. 35:17.570 --> 35:18.250 Sorry. 35:18.250 --> 35:23.170 So what happens in the beginning of the next year, 35:23.170 --> 35:27.970 year 3, well let's say our guy--so the hedge fund makes 35:27.972 --> 35:31.622 money and this time it made 3 percent, 35:31.619 --> 35:34.499 a crappier, sorry, a less good return, 35:34.500 --> 35:35.630 only 3 percent. 35:35.630 --> 35:37.120 God, it's on film. 35:37.119 --> 35:38.949 I'm glad that's going to live for posterity. 35:38.949 --> 35:44.929 Only a 3 percent return, and so the hedge fund which 35:44.929 --> 35:52.079 ended the year at 1,307 now by the next of this next year it's 35:52.081 --> 35:57.711 made 3 percent on that so it's up to 1,346, 35:57.710 --> 36:03.930 so 39 dollars, 3 percent on 1,300 so 1,346. 36:03.929 --> 36:06.139 Now of that who's got the money? 36:06.139 --> 36:13.529 Well, our original guy he's now made--everyone made 3 percent so 36:13.530 --> 36:16.580 his 107 turned into 110. 36:16.579 --> 36:19.229 The second guy's got 1,030 in the fund, 36:19.230 --> 36:24.860 and the third guy's got 206 in the fund and the total fund is 36:24.856 --> 36:28.166 1,346, Now let's suppose that our guy, 36:28.170 --> 36:30.880 this is the beginning of year 3, 36:30.880 --> 36:32.670 our first guy says, "3 percent, 36:32.670 --> 36:34.360 that's a terrible return. 36:34.360 --> 36:35.760 I'm taking my money out. 36:35.760 --> 36:36.680 I've had it. 36:36.679 --> 36:38.369 It's 110 dollars. 36:38.369 --> 36:39.349 That's what I have. 36:39.349 --> 36:42.339 I'm taking it out," and no one else does anything. 36:42.340 --> 36:45.420 So at the end of the year now he's down to zero and everybody 36:45.422 --> 36:48.662 else is where they were and the hedge fund thing has gone down a 36:48.659 --> 36:49.429 little bit. 36:49.429 --> 36:51.809 Well now next year the thing does even worse. 36:51.809 --> 36:53.909 It makes a 0 percent return. 36:53.909 --> 36:57.789 So everybody's money is just the same except that the second 36:57.789 --> 37:01.539 guy decides this is really getting lousy and he takes half 37:01.536 --> 37:02.716 his money out. 37:02.719 --> 37:04.349 So this is taking half his money out. 37:04.349 --> 37:05.619 What was his money? 37:05.619 --> 37:09.419 He was 1,112 and half of that is 556. 37:09.420 --> 37:12.280 So he takes half of it out leaving half behind, 37:12.275 --> 37:15.745 and the column on the right reduces what the hedge fund's 37:15.751 --> 37:16.871 total cash is. 37:16.869 --> 37:20.659 But now the hedge fund has a great year and it makes 50 37:20.657 --> 37:21.357 percent. 37:21.360 --> 37:35.200 Having made 50 percent--sorry, so this guy takes half his 37:35.202 --> 37:38.172 money out. 37:38.170 --> 37:41.700 At the beginning of the year the fund does badly then the 37:41.701 --> 37:43.721 fund--I skipped the 8 percent. 37:43.719 --> 37:45.909 There was an 8 percent return, sorry. 37:45.909 --> 37:47.179 Oh, what an idiot. 37:47.179 --> 37:51.679 Anyway, so the next year the fund returned not 0 percent it 37:51.679 --> 37:53.309 returned 8 percent. 37:53.309 --> 37:56.729 So the first guy after the 3 percent return this guy took his 37:56.726 --> 37:57.406 money out. 37:57.409 --> 38:00.889 The other guys left it in and then the fund had an 8 percent 38:00.889 --> 38:01.419 return. 38:01.420 --> 38:04.830 So it's a little bit better, but this guy decides to take 38:04.829 --> 38:06.109 half his money out. 38:06.110 --> 38:11.030 Then the fund has a 0 percent return and after that this guy 38:11.034 --> 38:15.004 decides to take his money out, half his money out, 38:15.001 --> 38:18.641 but then finally the last year the fund gives a 50 percent 38:18.637 --> 38:20.797 return, which is fantastic, 38:20.797 --> 38:22.637 so everybody does well. 38:22.639 --> 38:25.879 And now let's say they all decide to take their money out. 38:25.880 --> 38:31.800 So now there's nothing left in the fund, and they withdrew the 38:31.795 --> 38:32.955 total 934. 38:32.960 --> 38:35.130 So what I've done here, just to summarize it, 38:35.126 --> 38:37.786 is every year people are putting in money or taking out 38:37.788 --> 38:39.708 money at the beginning of the year. 38:39.710 --> 38:41.790 You can never take out more than you have or you can put 38:41.793 --> 38:42.213 money in. 38:42.210 --> 38:45.410 The fund earns returns over the whole year and then people, 38:45.409 --> 38:48.079 again, decide to take money out or put money in and then the 38:48.081 --> 38:50.211 fund earns a different return the next year, 38:50.210 --> 38:53.640 and eventually the fund returns all the money or people withdraw 38:53.637 --> 38:54.287 the money. 38:54.289 --> 38:58.479 So the question is how has the fund done? 38:58.480 --> 39:03.100 How would you summarize in one number how the fund has done 39:03.103 --> 39:05.973 over its 1,2, 3,4, 5 years of earning 39:05.972 --> 39:06.932 returns? 39:06.929 --> 39:08.389 That's the question. 39:08.389 --> 39:14.319 So this is a standard--this is obviously what happens every day 39:14.322 --> 39:16.142 with hedge funds. 39:16.139 --> 39:20.189 So how do hedge funds report how they've done historically? 39:20.190 --> 39:21.460 So do you have any suggestions? 39:21.460 --> 39:26.210 What would you do to summarize how the hedge fund has done? 39:26.210 --> 39:32.950 If you had to pick one number what would it be? 39:32.949 --> 39:36.749 How good an investor is the fund? 39:36.750 --> 39:37.700 Yeah? 39:37.699 --> 39:38.859 Student: Just multiply the return. 39:38.860 --> 39:40.980 Take a geometric average. 39:40.980 --> 39:45.930 Prof: So one thing you could do is you could say--he 39:45.934 --> 39:49.954 said literally multiply all of these returns. 39:49.949 --> 39:50.989 What does that mean? 39:50.989 --> 39:54.019 That means if you put 1 dollar in the fund at the beginning 39:54.018 --> 39:55.218 you'd earn 7 percent. 39:55.219 --> 39:57.939 If you left it there and never took it out you get another 3 39:57.938 --> 39:58.398 percent. 39:58.400 --> 40:01.380 Then you'd get 8 percent on top of that, then 0 percent, 40:01.376 --> 40:02.346 then 50 percent. 40:02.349 --> 40:05.399 Of course this is a multiplicative thing, 40:05.400 --> 40:09.980 so he says you'd get 1.07 times 1.03 times 1.08 times 1 times 40:09.978 --> 40:10.588 1.5. 40:10.590 --> 40:13.570 Multiplying all that would give you the number of dollars you'd 40:13.570 --> 40:16.600 have at the end of 5 years given that you put 1 dollar in at the 40:16.599 --> 40:18.329 beginning and never took it out. 40:18.329 --> 40:22.269 And if you wanted to annualize that he said take the geometric 40:22.268 --> 40:24.478 average, the fifth root of that and 40:24.480 --> 40:27.880 that's the constant rate of return that would have given you 40:27.882 --> 40:31.522 the same amount of money at the end that you would get by having 40:31.518 --> 40:35.088 left 1 dollar from the beginning in the fund all the way to the 40:35.094 --> 40:35.734 end. 40:35.730 --> 40:37.120 Is that clear to everybody? 40:37.119 --> 40:39.509 That seems like a logical thing to do. 40:39.510 --> 40:41.970 That's what money hedge funds do do, in fact. 40:41.969 --> 40:44.049 That's the number they tell you. 40:44.050 --> 40:49.080 Now, why might not that be a great number? 40:49.079 --> 40:51.509 Did everyone follow what his suggestion was? 40:51.510 --> 40:54.530 So by the way, his number's going to come out 40:54.534 --> 40:56.464 to be--well, I don't know. 40:56.460 --> 40:57.640 Anyway it's going to be some number. 40:57.639 --> 40:59.709 We could do that. 40:59.710 --> 41:01.340 In fact it wouldn't be that hard to do. 41:01.340 --> 41:07.520 Let's just do it. 41:07.519 --> 41:19.489 Sum, oh this wasn't a very--ah! 41:19.489 --> 41:21.189 How about equals? 41:21.190 --> 41:37.960 41:37.960 --> 41:49.980 Oh, dear, all right, circular reference. 41:49.980 --> 42:00.600 Equals sum. 42:00.599 --> 42:03.139 Oh, why did I get zero here? 42:03.139 --> 42:04.489 Oh, because I'm trying to multiply these. 42:04.489 --> 42:06.829 I'm adding instead, so equals. 42:06.829 --> 42:08.909 I'll just have to do it one by one. 42:08.909 --> 42:14.769 That times the next one, times the next one. 42:14.768 --> 42:16.538 There's obviously a much faster way of doing this. 42:16.539 --> 42:21.819 Times the next one, times that one and zero, 42:21.820 --> 42:24.000 that's what 1 dollar would have gotten you if you had put it in 42:24.000 --> 42:26.930 and kept it until the end, and now he's saying take this 42:26.931 --> 42:28.251 to the fifth power. 42:28.250 --> 42:36.320 So I'll take up this .2 enter. 42:36.320 --> 42:42.830 So 12.2 percent, now why isn't that the right 42:42.827 --> 42:44.157 number? 42:44.159 --> 42:49.739 Why might you think there should be another number? 42:49.739 --> 42:50.369 What's another number? 42:50.369 --> 42:53.209 What's the matter with that--way back there? 42:53.210 --> 42:58.290 Student: It's grossly inflated by that last year's 50 42:58.286 --> 42:59.746 percent return. 42:59.750 --> 43:01.440 Prof: Well, is it grossly inflated, 43:01.440 --> 43:03.130 but why is it grossly inflated by that? 43:03.130 --> 43:06.120 Student: There are going to be lots of years where it 43:06.117 --> 43:07.027 doesn't do that. 43:07.030 --> 43:08.600 Prof: That's true, but you've taken that into 43:08.601 --> 43:08.911 account. 43:08.909 --> 43:13.479 So the years we didn't do that well like the 0 percent return 43:13.476 --> 43:17.586 that brought the average down, so why is that a problem 43:17.585 --> 43:18.495 exactly? 43:18.500 --> 43:22.840 Yeah, it's averaging the good years with the bad years, 43:22.838 --> 43:23.238 so. 43:23.239 --> 43:23.929 Yeah? 43:23.929 --> 43:26.439 Student: As far as a measure of past performance it 43:26.440 --> 43:29.170 doesn't take into account that after three mediocre years a lot 43:29.172 --> 43:30.892 of money was removed from the fund. 43:30.889 --> 43:33.239 Prof: That's the crucial thing. 43:33.239 --> 43:39.269 So I didn't do extreme enough numbers. 43:39.268 --> 43:44.718 The crucial thing to take into account is that suppose you have 43:44.722 --> 43:48.952 a fund that starts off, many funds like my fund started 43:48.947 --> 43:52.497 off with very little money, but we did it at the right time 43:52.498 --> 43:54.628 because we knew that was a good time. 43:54.630 --> 43:55.950 You're going to see when the leverage cycle, 43:55.947 --> 43:56.527 we talk about it. 43:56.530 --> 43:58.830 It was at the bottom of the leverage cycle just like this 43:58.827 --> 43:59.317 past year. 43:59.320 --> 44:01.930 We're up 30 percent this year. 44:01.929 --> 44:03.849 So at the bottom of the leverage cycle you're going to 44:03.853 --> 44:04.583 have a great year. 44:04.579 --> 44:08.109 Of course we hardly had any money because the fund was just 44:08.112 --> 44:11.342 starting, and so we made 50 percent the first year. 44:11.340 --> 44:13.030 But then everybody said, "Oh, 44:13.030 --> 44:14.770 these guys must be geniuses," 44:14.768 --> 44:17.718 and they poured a huge amount of money into our fund, 44:17.719 --> 44:22.079 and let's say the next year we did 10 percent. 44:22.079 --> 44:24.519 Actually we had another great year the second year, 44:24.518 --> 44:27.198 but let's say that we did 10 percent the second year. 44:27.199 --> 44:31.489 So the young man in the front is saying you made 50 percent on 44:31.487 --> 44:35.637 pennies and then you made 10 percent on a gigantic amount of 44:35.635 --> 44:36.335 money. 44:36.340 --> 44:38.960 It isn't right to take the average of 50 percent and 10 44:38.956 --> 44:41.906 percent because almost all the money that you managed you made 44:41.914 --> 44:43.664 10 percent on not 50 percent on. 44:43.659 --> 44:44.639 That's his point. 44:44.639 --> 44:47.449 So how would you deal with his point? 44:47.449 --> 44:51.089 How could you figure out a way of computing the right return to 44:51.094 --> 44:54.504 compensate for the fact that some years you have a lot more 44:54.503 --> 44:57.153 money at stake than you have other years? 44:57.150 --> 44:57.770 Yes? 44:57.768 --> 44:58.908 Student: Take a weighted average? 44:58.909 --> 44:59.909 Prof: Take a weighted average. 44:59.909 --> 45:03.559 Well, how would you take the weighted average? 45:03.559 --> 45:06.469 Sounds a little complicated. 45:06.469 --> 45:08.569 That's what I'm going to do, but it's not immediately 45:08.570 --> 45:09.500 obvious how to do it. 45:09.500 --> 45:12.570 So I wouldn't have expected you to be able to answer that. 45:12.570 --> 45:14.300 You're right on the right track. 45:14.300 --> 45:16.580 So does anyone have anything else to say? 45:16.579 --> 45:17.999 Yep? 45:18.000 --> 45:21.070 Student: I guess you multiply each 45:21.074 --> 45:22.994 > 45:22.994 --> 45:26.684 , and then you add it all up and divide it by the 45:26.684 --> 45:28.994 > 45:28.989 --> 45:33.549 Prof: All right, so I'm going to now give you 45:33.552 --> 45:37.582 the answer which is a little bit like that. 45:37.579 --> 45:40.859 She's saying do some dollar weighted thing, 45:40.860 --> 45:45.550 and so you somehow weight the numbers by how much money there 45:45.547 --> 45:47.967 was invested for that year. 45:47.969 --> 45:51.259 So because there was a lot more money invested in year 3 than 45:51.255 --> 45:54.485 there was in year 1 that number should somehow have a bigger 45:54.487 --> 45:55.087 weight. 45:55.090 --> 45:59.310 And it's not exactly clear how the weights are going to get in 45:59.309 --> 46:03.319 there, but it's obvious that that's something like that you 46:03.322 --> 46:04.432 ought to do. 46:04.429 --> 46:10.539 So here's the mathematical solution that the internal rate 46:10.536 --> 46:13.426 of return or yield gives. 46:13.429 --> 46:23.479 So it says every year let's look at what happened in the 46:23.480 --> 46:24.760 fund. 46:24.760 --> 46:28.220 We shouldn't care about which investor put in which dollar. 46:28.219 --> 46:30.229 We care about how the fund managed dollars. 46:30.230 --> 46:32.590 The names of the investors don't make any difference. 46:32.590 --> 46:35.040 It's how did the fund manage its money. 46:35.039 --> 46:38.789 So in the first year the fund got 100 dollars. 46:38.789 --> 46:42.969 So as for producing money it produced a negative 100. 46:42.969 --> 46:44.729 Money went into the fund. 46:44.730 --> 46:46.240 That was the one guy invested. 46:46.239 --> 46:47.229 We don't care who it was. 46:47.230 --> 46:49.010 The total that went into the fund was 100. 46:49.010 --> 46:51.840 The second year 1,200 went into the fund. 46:51.840 --> 46:53.460 Those are the second two guys. 46:53.460 --> 46:56.080 The third year 110 came out. 46:56.079 --> 46:57.749 That was the first guy. 46:57.750 --> 47:01.360 The fourth year 556 came out. 47:01.360 --> 47:02.810 That was the second guy. 47:02.809 --> 47:06.699 This is beginning of the fifth year. 47:06.699 --> 47:10.079 The third guy took out 155 dollars, and then the last year 47:10.081 --> 47:13.761 the second and third guys took out everything that was left. 47:13.760 --> 47:17.930 So from the point of view of money creation and use this is 47:17.931 --> 47:22.101 every year what went into the fund and what came out of the 47:22.103 --> 47:24.193 fund, the net inflow out. 47:24.190 --> 47:28.250 So there are a bunch of numbers. 47:28.250 --> 47:32.320 So the question is, so the one number summary is 47:32.318 --> 47:35.838 what rate of return, it's called the internal rate 47:35.840 --> 47:38.480 of return which if you discounted all these numbers 47:38.480 --> 47:41.700 what would Fisher say if you discounted all these numbers? 47:41.699 --> 47:44.239 If you had to use just one interest rate, 47:44.237 --> 47:47.027 Fisher would say, what's the present value of 47:47.027 --> 47:48.357 these cash flows? 47:48.360 --> 47:50.740 Well, if the interest rate was 0 you just add up all the 47:50.739 --> 47:52.859 numbers and you're going to get a big positive. 47:52.860 --> 47:55.860 If the interest rate is infinity then that means that 47:55.858 --> 47:59.198 after the first year you're discounting everything to 0 and 47:59.204 --> 48:01.344 you're going to get negative 100. 48:01.340 --> 48:05.320 So you could say, what interest rate could you 48:05.320 --> 48:09.390 discount all the cash flows at to produce 0? 48:09.389 --> 48:12.689 That would be like saying at that interest rate, 48:12.688 --> 48:16.058 all the fund has done is rearranged its money. 48:16.059 --> 48:18.929 It's taken money in and put money out, but at that same 48:18.934 --> 48:21.494 constant interest rate the present value is 0. 48:21.489 --> 48:27.219 So it's allowed you to trade money across periods at this 48:27.217 --> 48:32.637 internal rate of return, the interest rate which makes 48:32.637 --> 48:35.397 the present value zero. 48:35.400 --> 48:38.030 So 10 percent turns out to be the right number. 48:38.030 --> 48:40.380 So if you discounted things by 10 percent, 48:40.380 --> 48:44.090 you see what the formula is, you take the inflow and you 48:44.094 --> 48:48.284 discount it by 1.10 to the first power and this you discount by 48:48.282 --> 48:53.392 1.10 to the second power, the inflow, the net outflow, 48:53.389 --> 48:57.209 I guess, which is 110 you discount by 48:57.208 --> 49:00.508 1.10 to the third power etcetera. 49:00.510 --> 49:03.810 You keep discounting by that and you get all the discounted 49:03.806 --> 49:04.486 net flows. 49:04.489 --> 49:07.429 You add them all up and you get practically nothing. 49:07.429 --> 49:10.429 That's adding them up and this is taking the square, 49:10.434 --> 49:14.154 and I used Solver to figure out what the right discount rate was 49:14.146 --> 49:15.676 to make all this zero. 49:15.679 --> 49:20.549 So that's the simple way of averaging, dollar weighting 49:20.547 --> 49:21.717 everything. 49:21.719 --> 49:24.519 You don't care about who the people are. 49:24.518 --> 49:27.278 You don't care about whether one guy's putting money in, 49:27.280 --> 49:29.640 another guy's taking it out at the same time. 49:29.639 --> 49:32.159 You just care about the net, and if you've got a bunch of 49:32.163 --> 49:34.053 net numbers, that's the net outflow, 49:34.048 --> 49:37.438 and you're trying to say, what's the single rate of 49:37.438 --> 49:38.068 return? 49:38.070 --> 49:42.440 The idea is to say at what interest rate? 49:42.440 --> 49:45.480 If there were a bank paying an interest rate and all those 49:45.483 --> 49:48.693 things discounted gave you zero that would be like saying the 49:48.688 --> 49:50.878 fund is functioning just like a bank. 49:50.880 --> 49:54.100 No matter when people put the money in or take it out they're 49:54.099 --> 49:57.159 always getting this rate of return which is 10 percent. 49:57.159 --> 50:00.139 So they're getting a constant 10 percent rate of return no 50:00.139 --> 50:03.489 matter when the money goes in or out and that kind of gives you a 50:03.485 --> 50:05.625 measure of how well the fund's doing. 50:05.630 --> 50:09.260 So that's the internal rate of return, or the yield to 50:09.264 --> 50:10.024 maturity. 50:10.018 --> 50:12.328 It says take the net cash flows every year. 50:12.329 --> 50:18.199 Find the number which when you discount at that number you get 50:18.195 --> 50:21.075 present value equal to zero. 50:21.079 --> 50:25.649 So it's 10 percent which is a different number from 12 50:25.648 --> 50:26.508 percent. 50:26.510 --> 50:30.140 Now before we got the geometric average of 12 percent. 50:30.139 --> 50:34.409 Now very typically this is the case that this internal rate of 50:34.414 --> 50:38.834 return is lower than the dollar return from putting the money in 50:38.827 --> 50:41.817 at the beginning, assuming the fund doesn't just 50:41.824 --> 50:43.574 collapse and go to zero at the end. 50:43.570 --> 50:44.380 So why is that? 50:44.380 --> 50:47.310 For funds that have survived typically that number, 50:47.306 --> 50:49.646 12 percent, is higher than 10 percent. 50:49.650 --> 50:51.970 Why would that be? 50:51.969 --> 50:55.839 What does that tell you about the world? 50:55.840 --> 50:58.340 Someone who hasn't--well, go ahead. 50:58.340 --> 51:00.610 Student: That it's easier to make money with a 51:00.606 --> 51:01.736 smaller amount of money? 51:01.739 --> 51:04.799 Prof: It tells you that, and how is it that the hedge 51:04.800 --> 51:06.410 fund--it could tell you that. 51:06.409 --> 51:08.409 It tells you that the hedge funds are doing better when they 51:08.409 --> 51:10.379 have a smaller amount of money than when they have a larger 51:10.376 --> 51:11.356 amount of money, exactly. 51:11.360 --> 51:14.070 You've concluded that it's easier to make money when you 51:14.067 --> 51:15.147 have a small amount. 51:15.150 --> 51:18.540 What's another possible explanation? 51:18.539 --> 51:20.929 Student: People normally invest a lot after a big year 51:20.932 --> 51:22.012 > 51:22.010 --> 51:22.500 Prof: Right. 51:22.500 --> 51:23.510 I think that's the reason. 51:23.510 --> 51:26.970 The reason is that people pour money into hedge funds just 51:26.965 --> 51:29.265 after they've done incredibly well, 51:29.268 --> 51:31.668 and they keep pouring money in, then eventually there's a blow 51:31.672 --> 51:31.872 up. 51:31.869 --> 51:36.079 And so when the blow up comes the hedge funds have zillions of 51:36.076 --> 51:39.106 dollars and they're losing a lot of money. 51:39.110 --> 51:41.410 Then everybody pulls their money out and that's when the 51:41.407 --> 51:43.997 cycle is going up and then all of a sudden the hedge funds have 51:43.996 --> 51:46.876 these huge returns again, but they hardly have any money. 51:46.880 --> 51:52.630 So, any other questions about this? 51:52.630 --> 51:58.840 All right, so internal rate of return is a way-- 51:58.840 --> 52:00.910 we are going to see that it has many shortcomings, 52:00.909 --> 52:03.499 but it's a way at getting at the idea, 52:03.500 --> 52:06.250 as several of you have said, that you can't just take the 52:06.248 --> 52:09.198 geometric average, which is what every hedge fund 52:09.201 --> 52:10.931 like ours always produces. 52:10.929 --> 52:13.079 That's the number we tell everybody because it's a better 52:13.076 --> 52:14.146 number than the other one. 52:14.150 --> 52:18.740 So the geometric average of the returns are, 52:18.739 --> 52:23.129 if you're an investor who puts 1 dollar in at the beginning and 52:23.128 --> 52:27.308 leaves it there forever what's your geometric average of all 52:27.306 --> 52:28.506 your returns. 52:28.510 --> 52:31.080 That's not a good reflection of how the hedge fund's done 52:31.081 --> 52:33.841 necessarily because some years the fund had a lot of money to 52:33.836 --> 52:34.476 work with. 52:34.480 --> 52:37.750 And so the average dollar didn't do that well, 52:37.750 --> 52:40.120 and now there's a question about how should you measure the 52:40.123 --> 52:42.143 average dollar, and I've given the internal 52:42.139 --> 52:42.899 rate of return. 52:42.900 --> 52:44.560 There are actually other formulas you could give. 52:44.559 --> 52:50.889 This is the most famous one. 52:50.889 --> 52:57.319 Now let's see how this internal rate of return is used all the 52:57.320 --> 52:59.640 time on Wall Street. 52:59.639 --> 53:03.129 By the way, if you're not following what I'm saying you 53:03.132 --> 53:05.012 should please interrupt me. 53:05.010 --> 53:11.840 So what if you took a bond, a simple coupon bond? 53:11.840 --> 53:13.600 What is a simple coupon bond? 53:13.599 --> 53:16.499 The yield to maturity of a simple coupon bond, 53:16.501 --> 53:20.371 I'm now on this lecture called yield, what is a simple coupon 53:20.369 --> 53:20.949 bond? 53:20.949 --> 53:24.739 A simple coupon bond pays the same coupon every year and then 53:24.742 --> 53:28.032 pays the principal and the coupon at its maturity. 53:28.030 --> 53:34.060 So the yield to maturity is going to be the price, 53:34.057 --> 53:40.577 which is like a negative payment--suppose you knew the 53:40.579 --> 53:43.409 price of this bond. 53:43.409 --> 53:46.459 If you knew the price of the bond, and so the bond is 53:46.456 --> 53:49.736 promising all these payments, how good a deal is that? 53:49.739 --> 53:53.139 Well, how good a deal it is they would say is you simply 53:53.135 --> 53:57.025 take this first negative payment and all these positive payments 53:57.027 --> 54:00.667 and find the unique interest rate which when you discount it 54:00.670 --> 54:03.080 will give you present value of 0. 54:03.079 --> 54:07.929 And so if this is a coupon bond, say paying 7 percent, 54:07.929 --> 54:10.829 say the face is 100, it pays 7 dollars forever, 54:10.829 --> 54:14.989 and 107 at the end, and the price is 105, 54:14.989 --> 54:21.479 what do you think the yield to maturity is going to be? 54:21.480 --> 54:23.240 Can you say anything qualitative about it? 54:23.239 --> 54:28.229 Suppose it's a 7 percent coupon bond, face of 100,10-year bond, 54:28.226 --> 54:32.806 no one thinks that it'll default, but its price is 105. 54:32.809 --> 54:38.259 What is the yield to maturity in that case do you suppose? 54:38.260 --> 54:41.450 Just a vague guess, I just want a qualitative 54:41.447 --> 54:42.097 number. 54:42.099 --> 54:44.909 Student: 6.7? 54:44.909 --> 54:53.019 Prof: 6.7, that's qualitatively wrong. 54:53.018 --> 54:54.448 Well, I mean it's not qualitatively wrong. 54:54.449 --> 54:55.539 No, it's qualitatively right. 54:55.539 --> 54:57.099 It could have been better. 54:57.099 --> 54:57.909 So he's right. 54:57.909 --> 55:03.239 So what if the price were 100 what would the yield to maturity 55:03.242 --> 55:03.682 be? 55:03.679 --> 55:05.779 Student: 7 percent. 55:05.780 --> 55:07.620 Prof: 7 percent, that's obvious, 55:07.621 --> 55:08.011 right? 55:08.010 --> 55:13.830 If it's a 7 percent coupon bond on face of 100 and its price is 55:13.831 --> 55:15.581 100, price = to the face, 55:15.581 --> 55:18.691 then obviously the thing that discounts you back to 100 is 55:18.693 --> 55:20.553 going to be 7 percent interest. 55:20.550 --> 55:23.920 So if the price were 100 the yield to maturity would just be 55:23.922 --> 55:24.612 7 percent. 55:24.610 --> 55:27.500 But I told you the price was 105, which is a lot more 55:27.501 --> 55:28.171 expensive. 55:28.170 --> 55:29.450 So it's a bad deal. 55:29.449 --> 55:31.589 So it's not going to be as good as 107. 55:31.590 --> 55:36.130 So it's not going to be 7 percent and he said 6.7. 55:36.130 --> 55:39.030 So I think it would be a little worse than that, 55:39.030 --> 55:41.870 but that's qualitatively just what I asked for, 55:41.869 --> 55:44.029 something worse than 7 percent. 55:44.030 --> 55:45.980 So who said 6.7 percent? 55:45.980 --> 55:47.620 You did. 55:47.619 --> 55:53.659 Student: I just took the price of the bond over the 55:53.657 --> 55:59.057 coupon payment and that's 6.7, but it's not the only 55:59.057 --> 56:02.127 > 56:02.130 --> 56:04.820 Prof: So that's another number. 56:04.820 --> 56:10.430 So I'm going to come back to your question. 56:10.429 --> 56:11.269 It's a good question. 56:11.268 --> 56:23.658 So do you all see that if you measured the yield to maturity 56:23.664 --> 56:33.124 on this bond--so the bond, remember, pays 7,7, 56:33.117 --> 56:39.627 7,107 and its price is 105. 56:39.630 --> 56:46.000 So the yield to maturity is going to be that number such 56:45.998 --> 56:53.058 that 105 = 7 over (1 the yield) 7 over (1 the yield) squared 7 56:53.063 --> 56:56.773 over (1 the yield) cubed ... 56:56.768 --> 57:03.348 107 over (1 yield) to the tenth, that's 105. 57:03.349 --> 57:09.269 So what we observed is that Y has to be less than 7 percent 57:09.266 --> 57:15.586 because if Y were exactly equal to 7 percent this would give us 57:15.592 --> 57:16.412 100. 57:16.409 --> 57:19.839 But this bond is more expensive, so you're paying more 57:19.842 --> 57:23.212 to get the same payments you would--than the face. 57:23.210 --> 57:25.420 You're paying more than the face to get the same payment. 57:25.420 --> 57:27.630 If the price were equal to the face it would be a 7 percent 57:27.634 --> 57:27.944 yield. 57:27.940 --> 57:30.740 So since you're paying more you're getting a worse deal, 57:30.739 --> 57:34.259 so it's pretty obvious that if you want to discount this number 57:34.255 --> 57:37.745 to more than 100, namely 105, Y is going to have 57:37.753 --> 57:39.883 to be less than 7 percent. 57:39.880 --> 57:41.420 So that's the first thing we said. 57:41.420 --> 57:42.860 Now what did he do? 57:42.860 --> 57:55.900 He gave a number and he said 7 over 105 which he said was about 57:55.896 --> 57:58.836 6.7 percent. 57:58.840 --> 58:11.270 So that number that he gave is called the current yield. 58:11.268 --> 58:15.998 It's another number people give, and he figured that was 58:15.996 --> 58:17.196 6.7 percent. 58:17.199 --> 58:25.999 So let's believe him that's 6.7 percent. 58:26.000 --> 58:41.450 How does that number compare to the yield to maturity, 58:41.449 --> 58:43.489 to Y? 58:43.489 --> 58:51.149 Well, we could compute this out on Excel since I'm doing so 58:51.150 --> 58:54.320 brilliantly at it now. 58:54.320 --> 59:02.180 So we could go 7,7, 7,7, 7,7, 7,7, 59:02.181 --> 59:05.281 7, and 107. 59:05.280 --> 59:13.350 Those are our payments and then we could try some yield to 59:13.353 --> 59:21.573 maturity, internal rate of return and let's guess 1.067. 59:21.570 --> 59:28.960 And now we'd say the cash flow is going to be this, 59:28.958 --> 59:32.798 is going to be the left. 59:32.800 --> 59:34.630 Oh dear, I have to number things. 59:34.630 --> 59:37.010 So again, there's probably some clever way of doing this. 59:37.010 --> 59:46.160 So this'll be--I forgot to write the year. 59:46.159 --> 59:52.209 Let's just add this. 59:52.210 --> 59:56.690 Equals up 1 enter. 59:56.690 --> 59:57.980 So I'm just going to copy this. 59:57.980 --> 1:00:05.740 All right, so now I've numbered all the years. 1:00:05.739 --> 1:00:14.609 Equals up 1 enter and now control copy. 1:00:14.610 --> 1:00:16.970 So I've numbered all the years here and here are the payments. 1:00:16.969 --> 1:00:24.129 And now at this yield to maturity I'm going to go equal 1:00:24.132 --> 1:00:32.622 the thing on the left divided by the yield to maturity that we're 1:00:32.619 --> 1:00:37.129 guessing raised to this power. 1:00:37.130 --> 1:00:43.800 Now I can just copy that and I've got all these cash flows. 1:00:43.800 --> 1:00:45.790 Oh, what did I do that time? 1:00:45.789 --> 1:00:47.049 Student: < 1:00:47.872 conversation>> 1:00:47.869 --> 1:00:48.729 Prof: What? 1:00:48.730 --> 1:00:52.290 Student: < 1:00:54.603 conversation>> 1:00:54.599 --> 1:00:55.589 Prof: Control copy, sorry. 1:00:55.590 --> 1:00:59.420 Student: < 1:01:01.900 conversation>> 1:01:01.900 --> 1:01:02.920 Prof: Control copy, right? 1:01:02.920 --> 1:01:04.280 So I just want to copy this? 1:01:04.280 --> 1:01:05.430 Student: < 1:01:06.182 conversation>> 1:01:06.179 --> 1:01:06.929 Prof: Oh, I see. 1:01:06.929 --> 1:01:09.309 Yeah, yeah, yeah, right, right, 1:01:09.313 --> 1:01:12.893 right, so here I've got the--you are right. 1:01:12.889 --> 1:01:17.029 So there's a trick here which I forgot which is the discount 1:01:17.027 --> 1:01:19.607 rate, the internal rate of return E 1:01:19.605 --> 1:01:26.285 I've got to put a dollar sign, dollar E, dollar 1 so that way 1:01:26.289 --> 1:01:29.709 it remembers the spot. 1:01:29.710 --> 1:01:35.350 So now when I copy it it's going to remember that. 1:01:35.349 --> 1:01:36.779 Student: B1. 1:01:36.780 --> 1:01:37.660 Prof: What's B1? 1:01:37.659 --> 1:01:40.089 Student: < 1:01:41.658 conversation>> 1:01:41.659 --> 1:01:42.819 Prof: Oh, B1. 1:01:42.820 --> 1:01:52.230 Thank you, so there are two mistakes, B1. 1:01:52.230 --> 1:01:55.990 Now, control copy. 1:01:55.989 --> 1:01:58.899 So I'm supposed to be showing you how easy it is to do this, 1:01:58.902 --> 1:02:00.782 but--all right, so anyway that's it. 1:02:00.780 --> 1:02:03.890 So if you see for each number here I've got the payments for 1:02:03.885 --> 1:02:06.935 every year and I've discounted them by taking this internal 1:02:06.936 --> 1:02:11.146 rate of return, and now I just have to sum all 1:02:11.148 --> 1:02:11.778 this. 1:02:11.780 --> 1:02:23.690 Equals sum parenthesis. 1:02:23.690 --> 1:02:24.810 Oh shit. 1:02:24.809 --> 1:02:27.779 Student: < 1:02:29.697 conversation>> 1:02:29.699 --> 1:02:31.269 Prof: I'm trying to sum it, you're right. 1:02:31.268 --> 1:02:37.588 So here equals, I want to sum all these. 1:02:37.590 --> 1:02:39.760 So what did I do wrong? 1:02:39.760 --> 1:02:42.880 Student: C1 colon C10. 1:02:42.880 --> 1:02:48.010 Prof: C1 colon C10, that's what I thought I did, 1:02:48.005 --> 1:02:50.375 but obviously I didn't. 1:02:50.380 --> 1:02:56.490 Good, and now we can do this and square it. 1:02:56.489 --> 1:03:05.849 So that's the thing I want to minimize, and so now I'm going 1:03:05.847 --> 1:03:12.987 to Tools, Solver, Min, C12 by concentrating on 1:03:12.987 --> 1:03:17.267 this number, and solve. 1:03:17.268 --> 1:03:22.618 Student: < 1:03:26.077 conversation>> 1:03:26.079 --> 1:03:26.939 Prof: All right, what did I do? 1:03:26.940 --> 1:03:31.610 Student: < 1:03:34.644 conversation>> 1:03:34.639 --> 1:03:36.319 Prof: Here's the sum, here's the... 1:03:36.320 --> 1:03:40.110 Student: The original price. 1:03:40.110 --> 1:03:41.340 Prof: Oh, the original price. 1:03:41.340 --> 1:03:42.140 Ah ha! 1:03:42.139 --> 1:03:43.889 Thank you very much. 1:03:43.889 --> 1:03:47.199 So we need the original price of 105. 1:03:47.199 --> 1:03:49.779 Very good, so I see that preparing this would have 1:03:49.784 --> 1:03:50.264 helped. 1:03:50.260 --> 1:03:51.860 So here's the sum. 1:03:51.860 --> 1:03:59.660 So we just summed all these things, and here we're going 1:03:59.661 --> 1:04:04.771 to--so we're summing those, right? 1:04:04.768 --> 1:04:12.888 So I summed all these and then I've got the original price 105 1:04:12.885 --> 1:04:13.945 enter. 1:04:13.949 --> 1:04:29.309 Now we'll add equals this plus this. 1:04:29.309 --> 1:04:32.589 Student: < 1:04:34.708 conversation>> 1:04:34.710 --> 1:04:46.570 Prof: You're right, this minus that. 1:04:46.570 --> 1:04:52.440 And now we want to square this, equals up squared enter and now 1:04:52.443 --> 1:04:54.153 we'll do Solver. 1:04:54.150 --> 1:04:56.880 Hopefully there isn't another mistake. 1:04:56.880 --> 1:05:15.620 So Tools, Solver, so I want that times E1. 1:05:15.619 --> 1:05:17.789 Oh, that's very bad. 1:05:17.789 --> 1:05:23.029 Anyway, you can solve it using Solver and it's extremely simple 1:05:23.030 --> 1:05:26.920 to do, and a child could learn how to do it. 1:05:26.920 --> 1:05:31.490 So we get Solver and we solve all this, and you should be able 1:05:31.490 --> 1:05:34.340 to use Excel with no problem at all. 1:05:34.340 --> 1:05:38.170 So the question is what are the relationships between the 1:05:38.170 --> 1:05:42.210 current yield and the yield to maturity, and suppose there's 1:05:42.206 --> 1:05:44.256 some actual interest rate. 1:05:44.260 --> 1:05:51.390 So there's an actual market interest rate of, 1:05:51.389 --> 1:05:56.249 say, 6 percent or something. 1:05:56.250 --> 1:05:59.860 So those are the things that we want to sort out now in the next 1:05:59.860 --> 1:06:00.720 five minutes. 1:06:00.719 --> 1:06:09.779 So let me go back to the notes and we'll re-ask all the 1:06:09.777 --> 1:06:12.627 questions here. 1:06:12.630 --> 1:06:13.260 You can see that's Solver. 1:06:13.260 --> 1:06:25.890 I've broken Solver. 1:06:25.889 --> 1:06:31.889 Suppose that there were an actual interest rate in the 1:06:31.891 --> 1:06:36.801 economy and our bond, the bond that was 7,7, 1:06:36.795 --> 1:06:40.865 7,107, if the actual interest rate was, 1:06:40.869 --> 1:06:47.009 say, 6 percent the price of the bond would be more than 100. 1:06:47.010 --> 1:06:50.140 So some price which will be the present value will be greater 1:06:50.143 --> 1:06:52.343 than 100, obviously, because it's 1:06:52.338 --> 1:06:56.368 paying--if the interest rate's only 6 percent this is giving 1:06:56.365 --> 1:06:57.795 you more than 100. 1:06:57.800 --> 1:07:05.830 Now, the current yield is 7 over the present value, 1:07:05.829 --> 1:07:11.609 exactly analogous to what he said. 1:07:11.610 --> 1:07:14.120 So if someone calls you on the phone, 1:07:14.119 --> 1:07:15.689 you haven't gotten these calls yet, 1:07:15.690 --> 1:07:19.550 but when you get older you'll get--they're screened now, 1:07:19.550 --> 1:07:22.410 so it's harder to get these, but it used to be a few years 1:07:22.414 --> 1:07:25.284 ago you'd get called on the phone quite often and somebody 1:07:25.278 --> 1:07:27.288 would say he's running a bond fund, 1:07:27.289 --> 1:07:30.369 and the bond fund is really doing great, 1:07:30.369 --> 1:07:34.519 and he wants to tell you that the bonds they have in the fund 1:07:34.518 --> 1:07:38.458 last year paid a current yield of 7 over the present value 1:07:38.460 --> 1:07:42.750 which is much bigger than the interest rate of 6 percent, 1:07:42.750 --> 1:07:46.490 and therefore you should buy his bonds. 1:07:46.489 --> 1:07:52.469 Now, what can you say about that? 1:07:52.469 --> 1:07:55.749 Suppose somebody tells you there's a market price for the 1:07:55.751 --> 1:07:58.061 bonds, which we know is the present 1:07:58.056 --> 1:08:00.716 value at the interest rate of 6 percent, 1:08:00.719 --> 1:08:02.789 and he tells you that, "Look, 1:08:02.789 --> 1:08:05.139 look at the market value I got last year, 1:08:05.139 --> 1:08:08.519 the yield I got; the current yield I got on 1:08:08.518 --> 1:08:09.218 these bonds. 1:08:09.219 --> 1:08:12.369 The present value was some number bigger than 100, 1:08:12.367 --> 1:08:16.287 but I take 7 over the present value and I get something bigger 1:08:16.287 --> 1:08:17.507 than 6 percent. 1:08:17.510 --> 1:08:20.750 At your bank you're only getting 6 percent, 1:08:20.751 --> 1:08:24.611 so therefore you should invest in my fund." 1:08:24.609 --> 1:08:31.219 Is that a good argument to invest in his fund? 1:08:31.220 --> 1:08:32.280 Why not? 1:08:32.279 --> 1:08:45.679 1:08:45.680 --> 1:08:55.830 Now, this bond is called a premium bond because the price 1:08:55.827 --> 1:09:05.237 is bigger than the face, and a discount bond means the 1:09:05.242 --> 1:09:13.192 price is less than the face, and a par bond, 1:09:13.194 --> 1:09:19.094 the price equals the face. 1:09:19.090 --> 1:09:25.290 So just because a bond pays a coupon of 7-- 1:09:25.288 --> 1:09:27.518 it may be when the bond was issued everybody thought the 1:09:27.520 --> 1:09:29.590 interest rate was going to be 7 percent forever, 1:09:29.590 --> 1:09:33.100 so that's why they picked a coupon of 7 so that the price 1:09:33.103 --> 1:09:36.933 when they first issued it would be equal to its face value. 1:09:36.930 --> 1:09:40.240 But maybe the next day, so it's still a 10-year bond, 1:09:40.240 --> 1:09:43.550 practically no time has changed, but unexpectedly the 1:09:43.552 --> 1:09:45.912 interest rates fell to 6 percent. 1:09:45.908 --> 1:09:49.798 If you take the same coupon bond paying 7 all the time at 6 1:09:49.795 --> 1:09:53.805 percent interest its price is obviously going to go up in the 1:09:53.814 --> 1:09:57.704 market because everybody is going to discount the 7s, 1:09:57.698 --> 1:10:00.438 not at 7 percent, but at 6 percent and get a 1:10:00.439 --> 1:10:02.479 number that's bigger than 100. 1:10:02.479 --> 1:10:06.999 So you're going to have to pay more for the bond because the 1:10:06.996 --> 1:10:08.906 present value's higher. 1:10:08.908 --> 1:10:13.268 However, people who now will try and market the bond they're 1:10:13.268 --> 1:10:16.048 going to tell you, "Well, look at the market 1:10:16.047 --> 1:10:17.807 price," whatever the market price is. 1:10:17.810 --> 1:10:20.760 So the current yield is the market price. 1:10:20.760 --> 1:10:23.410 They'll say, "Look at the market price. 1:10:23.408 --> 1:10:25.148 This is what we bought the bonds for. 1:10:25.149 --> 1:10:25.989 I'm a fund. 1:10:25.988 --> 1:10:31.078 I went out and bought these bonds. 1:10:31.078 --> 1:10:34.938 Look at the price I paid and I got 7 dollars for these bonds 1:10:34.940 --> 1:10:38.930 this year in income and 7 over the market price of the bond is 1:10:38.932 --> 1:10:43.042 bigger than 6 percent, so I was doing a great job. 1:10:43.038 --> 1:10:45.328 You should invest in my fund." 1:10:45.328 --> 1:10:49.278 So, that can't be a correct thing to say or a persuasive 1:10:49.279 --> 1:10:51.919 thing to say, because the market price 1:10:51.916 --> 1:10:55.566 reflected the fact that the interest rates were 6 percent. 1:10:55.569 --> 1:10:59.289 Everybody was properly computing the present value, 1:10:59.288 --> 1:11:01.858 and let's say the market price was equal to the present value, 1:11:01.859 --> 1:11:07.199 the present value would indeed be greater than 100 and in fact 1:11:07.199 --> 1:11:12.279 the current yield would be more than the interest rate of 6 1:11:12.279 --> 1:11:13.329 percent. 1:11:13.329 --> 1:11:20.649 So why is that? 1:11:20.649 --> 1:11:35.339 So, theorem, if market price equals present 1:11:35.344 --> 1:11:55.294 value at a going interest rate then the current yield on a 1:11:55.287 --> 1:12:15.577 premium bond is always greater than the interest rate. 1:12:15.579 --> 1:12:19.629 So why is that? 1:12:19.630 --> 1:12:22.390 So in this case, if I hadn't screwed up the 1:12:22.389 --> 1:12:25.739 Excel we would have calculated the present value. 1:12:25.738 --> 1:12:30.278 So 7,7, 7,107 there's only a 6 percent interest. 1:12:30.279 --> 1:12:33.789 So everybody taught by Irving Fisher computes the new present 1:12:33.792 --> 1:12:37.362 value which of course is bigger than 100 and that's the market 1:12:37.363 --> 1:12:37.953 price. 1:12:37.948 --> 1:12:43.708 Some unscrupulous salesman starts a fund, 1:12:43.710 --> 1:12:46.240 buys the bond for whatever this present value, 1:12:46.238 --> 1:12:49.158 the market price is, then goes out to a bunch of 1:12:49.164 --> 1:12:50.764 clients, potential clients, 1:12:50.759 --> 1:12:53.839 investors, and says, "Look, my very first year 1:12:53.837 --> 1:12:57.707 in business I spent a little more than 100 dollars and I got 1:12:57.706 --> 1:13:01.636 7 dollars as a coupon and 7 over this little more than 100 is 1:13:01.640 --> 1:13:05.510 giving me at current yield that's more than 6 percent. 1:13:05.510 --> 1:13:06.980 I beat the interest rate. 1:13:06.979 --> 1:13:08.859 You should invest in me, and by the way, 1:13:08.858 --> 1:13:11.698 I'll charge you a little fee to do that because I'm doing so 1:13:11.698 --> 1:13:12.468 great." 1:13:12.470 --> 1:13:15.700 Now, that's always going to be the case so it has to be that he 1:13:15.697 --> 1:13:18.037 really hasn't accomplished anything at all. 1:13:18.038 --> 1:13:23.178 So why is it easy to see that whenever I computed the present 1:13:23.179 --> 1:13:27.119 value it was going to have to be more than-- 1:13:27.118 --> 1:13:30.208 this current yield would always be more than 6 percent. 1:13:30.210 --> 1:13:31.180 How do I know that? 1:13:31.180 --> 1:13:33.280 Yep? 1:13:33.279 --> 1:13:37.389 Student: Because of the face value that's going to be at 1:13:37.391 --> 1:13:41.111 the end at maturity isn't going to reflect that increased 1:13:41.106 --> 1:13:43.956 interest or relatively higher interest. 1:13:43.960 --> 1:13:45.910 It's going to be the original face value. 1:13:45.909 --> 1:13:48.319 Prof: Exactly. 1:13:48.319 --> 1:13:52.989 So let's say, to keep this simpler, 1:13:52.993 --> 1:14:00.693 let's suppose these were 10s everywhere, and the interest 1:14:00.690 --> 1:14:05.090 rate went down to 5 percent. 1:14:05.090 --> 1:14:09.710 Now, what's going to be the present value of this bond? 1:14:09.710 --> 1:14:12.150 It's not going to be 200, right? 1:14:12.149 --> 1:14:20.229 If the bond paid 10,10, 210, suppose I have something 1:14:20.230 --> 1:14:28.780 paying 10-10-10 and 110, and the coupon is 5 percent. 1:14:28.779 --> 1:14:36.209 The present value is going to be less than 200. 1:14:36.210 --> 1:14:40.280 The coupon is always double the interest rate, 1:14:40.279 --> 1:14:43.009 so it looks like that's what you'd get if you had 200 1:14:43.011 --> 1:14:44.661 dollars, but at the end, 1:14:44.658 --> 1:14:47.718 as he's saying, you're only going to get 110 1:14:47.720 --> 1:14:48.790 and not 210. 1:14:48.788 --> 1:14:52.818 So this present value of this thing has to be less than 200. 1:14:52.819 --> 1:14:57.409 So if you double the coupon--if you halve the interest rate, 1:14:57.408 --> 1:14:59.268 the interest rate was originally 10 percent, 1:14:59.270 --> 1:15:02.870 if you cut the interest rate in half to 5 percent it looks like 1:15:02.868 --> 1:15:05.768 your annual coupon is double the interest rate, 1:15:05.770 --> 1:15:09.320 but at the end you don't get principal that's double the 1:15:09.315 --> 1:15:10.665 original principal. 1:15:10.670 --> 1:15:12.980 All you did was double--relative to the interest 1:15:12.978 --> 1:15:15.238 rate of 5 percent, the coupon's twice as big as 1:15:15.238 --> 1:15:17.398 you normally expect, but the face isn't. 1:15:17.399 --> 1:15:20.669 So therefore, this has to be worth less than 1:15:20.672 --> 1:15:21.132 200. 1:15:21.130 --> 1:15:25.650 If it were 200 at 5 percent it would give you 10, 1:15:25.649 --> 1:15:28.719 10,10, 10,10, 210, but this gives you 10, 1:15:28.720 --> 1:15:33.740 10,10, 110, so obviously the present value is less than 200, 1:15:33.738 --> 1:15:37.528 but therefore 10 over something less than 200 is going to be 1:15:37.527 --> 1:15:38.937 more than 5 percent. 1:15:38.939 --> 1:15:42.939 So that's his intuitive proof, which is the essence of the 1:15:42.938 --> 1:15:46.738 thing, that if ever you have a coupon 1:15:46.743 --> 1:15:52.883 bond that's a premium bond then the current yield is always 1:15:52.881 --> 1:15:55.741 above the interest rate. 1:15:55.738 --> 1:16:00.268 So you can always advertise it as having a spectacular current 1:16:00.266 --> 1:16:04.346 yield when in fact it's just priced perfectly fairly. 1:16:04.350 --> 1:16:07.240 So I'm going to just continue this story of what's the right 1:16:07.239 --> 1:16:09.789 way to measure things and how you can get confused by 1:16:09.787 --> 1:16:11.697 measuring the wrong way next class. 1:16:11.699 --> 1:16:16.999